Public disclosure in acquisitions

AuthorWenyuan Xu,Avanidhar Subrahmanyam
Published date01 January 2018
Date01 January 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/rfe.1017
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Public disclosure in acquisitions
Avanidhar Subrahmanyam
|
Wenyuan Xu
Anderson Graduate School of
Management, University of California at
Los Angeles, Los Angeles, CA, USA
Correspondence
Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, Anderson
Graduate School of Management,
University of California at Los Angeles,
Los Angeles, CA, USA.
Email: asubrahm@anderson.ucla.edu
Abstract
This paper analyzes firmsoptimal choice of information disclosure beforean acquisi-
tion. The intuition is that value-maximizing firms face the following tradeoffs. First, a
more precise disclosure reduces risk premia. Second, too precise a disclosure that
allows targets to profit increases the price paid for the target in an acquisition. The
main conclusion is that firm chooses to disclose either all information or the minimum
information required by the regulators, depending on the disclosure requirements,
investorsrisk aversion, and the uncertainty embedded in technology shocks.
KEYWORDS
asymmetric information, information disclosure, market efficiency
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Public firms frequently release information to the public, sometimes even beyond what is required by regulation. Research-
ing the determinants of firms disclosure policy helps understand how firm actively changes its information environment. It
also contributes to determining the optimal amount of disclosure regulation.
As Healy and Palepu (2001) point out, there are six factors impacting managersdisclosure decisions: capital market
transactions (e.g., cost of capital effects), corporate control contests, stock compensation , litigation costs, proprietary costs,
and management talent signaling. In this paper, we focus on the cost of capital and proprietary costs.
Due to an adverse selection problem, managers have the incentive to voluntarily disclose information and reduce the cost
of capital. Myers and Majluf (1984) indicate that firms have the incentive to disclose information voluntarily when making
public offerings. The higher the information asymmetry between management and shareholder, the higher the risk associated
with the security and thus the lower the price. Similarly, Barry and Brown (1985, 1986) and Merton (1987) argue that when
managers have superior information, investors demand an information risk premium if this information risk is not diversifi-
able. Diamond and Verrecchia (1991) and Kim and Verrecchia (1994) suggest that voluntary disclosure reduces the informa-
tion asymmetry between uninformed and informed investors, increases the liquidity of a firm s stock and raises the price.
Easley and OHara (2004) believe that uninformed traders will face bigger risk when facing information asymmetry because
informed traders can shift their weight to adjust for new information. There is also plenty of direct and indirect evidence sup-
porting this view. Botosan (1997) shows that for firms with low analyst following, the cost of capital decreases in the degree
of voluntary disclosure. Botosan and Plumlee (2000) find a negative relation between cost of capital and analyst rankings of
annual report disclosures. Gelb and Zarowin (2002) find that firms with high disclosure ratings have high stock prices relative
to firms with low disclosure ratings. Welker (1995), Healy, Hutton, and Palepu (1999), Leuz and Verrecchia (2000), and Coller
and Yohn (1997) document that bid-ask spreads are lower for firms with higher level of disclosure. This finding could be
viewed as an indirect support since research (e.g., Brennan & Subrahmanyam 1996) suggest that bid-ask spreads are positively
related to the cost of capital. A survey by Graham, Harvey, and Rajgopal (2005) finds that more than four in five of the execu-
tives in their sample concur that the cost of capital or reduction of information risk is a motivation for voluntary disclosures.
However, firms might not adopt a full disclosure policy in reality. The unraveling result (Milgrom, 1981) implies that firm
may hide information in equilibrium when disclosure is costly. A proprietary cost is often introduced to invoke partial disclo-
sure. The idea is that firm may strategically hide information from the market to remain competitive in the pro duct market. The
Received: 6 December 2017
|
Accepted: 21 December 2017
DOI: 10.1002/rfe.1017
Rev Financ Econ. 2018;36:311. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rfe ©2018 The University of New Orleans
|
3

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT