Property Rights and the Presumptions of Merger Analysis

Published date01 June 1994
DOI10.1177/0003603X9403900203
AuthorWilliam J. Lynk
Date01 June 1994
Subject MatterArticle
The Antitrust Bulletin/Summer 1994
Property rights and the
presumptions
of
merger
analysis
BY WILLIAM J. LYNK*
Both common sense and economic theory demonstrate that
the
competitive
behavior
and
financial
performance
of
nonprofit
hospitals-including
the incentive to raise prices
when
faced
with
less
competition-will
not
differ
materially from investor-owned hospitals.
363
Robert E. Bloch,
Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of Justice.
Antitrust
enforcement
investigations
of
proposed
mergers
are
focused
by one central question: Will the merger result in a price
increase
in the
affected
market? This, the
ultimate
question,
is
*Lexecon Inc., Chicago.
AUTHOR'S
NOTE: An earlier version
of
this article was
presented
at
aContemporary Policy Issues session at the 68th annual conference
of
the Western Economic Association International (June 23,
1993;
Lake
Tahoe, NV). I thank Thomas Campbell, Dennis Carlton,
Alan
Fisher,
Sam Peltzman, Margaret Sanderson, William Shear, Jeffrey Teske, and
Lawrence Wu for helpful comments on an earlier draft, none
of
whom
bears responsibility for any remaining errors or omissions.
©1994 by Federal Legal Publications, Inc.
364
The antitrust bulletin
generally assumed to be functionally identical to the penultimate
question: Will the merger create market powerf" And the reason
for assuming that the same reply answers both questions is simple.
In virtually all challenged mergers the parties to the transaction
are for-profit firms, and if the profit-maximization assumption
means anything,
it
means that any profit opportunity that can be
taken, will be taken.
The antitrust enforcement agencies are veterans at for-profit
merger analysis, but have had much less opportunity to analyze
the conduct of nonprofit firms." Perhaps as a result, the prevailing
presumption in government merger review seems to be that "for-
profit v. nonprofit" is a distinction without adifference; specifi-
cally, that a
nonprofit
merger
that
creates market
power
(the
penultimate question) is just as likely to result in a price increase
(the ultimate question) as an otherwise identical for-profit merger.
As I show in the analysis below, that presumption is baseless in
many, though not all, mergers of nonprofit hospitals. Analyses of
merger
policy
usually ask:
What
are the
circumstances
under
which a firm that wants to raise price, cannot? In contrast, I ask
the transpose
of
that question: What are the circumstances under
which a firm that can raise price, will not?
If
my analysis is cor-
rect, it implies that, by the agencies' failure to incorporate prop-
erly
the
pertinent
property
rights
issues
into
their
analytical
process, they have probably discouraged hospital mergers that in
fact were unlikely to result in increased prices to consumers.
Market power is the ability of the merged firm, with a now-higher
market share, to profitably make a price hike stick, either unilaterally or
with the cooperation of other firms in the now-more-concentrated market.
See William M. Landes &Richard A. Posner, Market Power in Antitrust
Cases, 94
HARv.
L.
REV.
937 (1981).
Most of that limited experience has been in the hospital industry;
see U.S. v. Rockford Memorial Corp., 898 F.2d 1278 (7th Cir. 1990);
U.S. v. Carilion Health System and Roanoke Valley Hospital, 892 F.2d
1042 (4th Cir. 1989); FTC v. University Health, 938 F.2d 1206 (11th Cir.
1991); and In re Adventist Health System/West and Ukiah Adventist
Hospital, F.T.C. Dkt. 9234 (1994).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT