Productivity, Structural Change and Latin American Development

AuthorCarlos Gustavo Machicado,Felix Rioja,Antonio Saravia
Date01 August 2014
Published date01 August 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12106
Productivity, Structural Change and Latin
American Development
Antonio Saravia, Carlos Gustavo Machicado, and Felix Rioja*
Abstract
We calibrate a simple neoclassical growth model adapted to illustrate a process of structural transformation
or industrialization to a group of nine South American countries. The paper shows that low levels of agri-
cultural productivity can substantially delay the process of industrialization, which, together with low levels
of non-agricultural productivity observed in recent decades, satisfactorily explains the significant differ-
ences in gross domestic product (GDP) per capita levels among the countries in our sample. The results
suggest that Argentina underwent the process of industrialization first followed by Uruguay, Chile, Brazil,
Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, Paraguay and Bolivia. The model predicts that the ranking of these countries in
terms of GDP per capita would follow this order until convergence occurs. The empirical evidence confirms
the prediction of the model with the exceptions of Uruguay and Chile which caught up with Argentina in
terms of GDP per capita levels in the late 1980s.
1. Introduction
Trying to understand the origins of the large disparity in income per capita levels
between rich and poor countries has been an enduring research question. While
several factors explain different parts of the puzzle, there is widespread agreement
that one of the prominent reasons for this disparity is that poor countries started the
process of industrialization much later than their rich counterparts and that the indus-
trialization process is slow (Lucas, 2000).
On this line of argument, Gollin, Parente and Rogerson (2002, GPR hereafter),
developed a model of structural transformation that explains why countries industrial-
ize at different dates and why industrialization proceeds slowly. Using a basic neoclas-
sical growth model modified to include both an agricultural and a non-agricultural
sector, GPR (2002) argue that countries begin the process of industrialization only
after being able to satisfy their basic agricultural needs (food). At this point, resources
are freed up from the agricultural sector and moved to the non-agricultural sector as
the industrialization process begins. Given that low agricultural productivity can sig-
nificantly delay the point at which countries are able to satisfy their basic agricultural
needs, low agricultural productivity can also delay the process of industrialization and
result in the country falling behind the leaders in terms of income per capita.1
In order to study the effect of agricultural productivity, GPR (2002) set non-
agricultural productivity, as well as the rate of technological progress in both the
agricultural and non-agricultural sectors, constant and equal across the modeled
economies. As a result, the modeled economies converge in the long run and each
* Saravia: Eugene W. Stetson School of Business & Economics, Mercer University, 1400 Coleman Avenue,
Macon, GA 31207, USA. Tel: +1-404-625-2116; Fax: +1-678-547-6160; E-mail: saravia_av@mercer.edu.
Machicado: Institute for Advanced Development Studies, 6115 Av. Hector Ormachea, La Paz, Bolivia.
E-mail: cmachicado@inesad.edu.bo. Rioja: Georgia State University, P.O. Box 3992, Atlanta, GA 30302,
USA. E-mail: frioja@gsu.edu.
Review of Development Economics, 18(3), 610–624, 2014
DOI:10.1111/rode.12106
© 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT