Privatization and Flexibility: Legal and Practical Aspects of Interjurisdictional Transfer of Prisoners

AuthorDavid Shichor,Dale K. Sechrest
Published date01 September 2002
DOI10.1177/003288550208200305
Date01 September 2002
Subject MatterArticles
THE PRISON JOURNAL / September 2002Shichor, Sechrest / PRIVATIZATION AND FLEXIBILITY
PRIVATIZATION AND FLEXIBILITY:
LEGAL AND PRACTICAL ASPECTS
OF INTERJURISDICTIONAL
TRANSFER OF PRISONERS
DAVID SHICHOR
DALE K. SECHREST
California State University, San Bernardino
One of the current issues in punishment and corrections is the privatization of con-
finement facilities (prisons and jails). Because private,for-profit correctional compa-
nies try to achieve maximum efficiencyin filling beds to ensure profits, they are likely
to use the transfer of prisoners from one jurisdiction to another more often than do
public agencies. In many cases, this may occur without the agreement or the knowl-
edge of government authorities, local officials,and citizens. This article reviews some
of the legal and practicalissues involved with transfer policies and looks into some of
the recent cases of interjurisdictional transfersby private corrections companies and
their implications for prisoners, their families, governmentauthorities, monitors, and
host communities.
It is a commonplace observation that the sociopolitical climate in Amer-
ica has become more conservative since the 1970s. This development also
had an impact on penal philosophy and practice. As Feeley and Simon (1992)
pointed out, a “new penology” has emerged in which “increasing primacy
[is] given to the efficient control of internal system processes in place of the
traditional objectives of rehabilitation and crime control.”Accordingly, new
policies were developed that “targetoffenders as an aggregate in place of tra-
ditional techniques for individualizing or creating equity” (Feeley & Simon,
1992, p. 450).
This approach puts a strong emphasis on the control of “dangerous” popu-
lations and the effective management of the criminal justice system. These
developments were reflected in the get tough attitude toward crime, the dec-
laration of “war on drugs,” the legislation of severe penalties culminating in
more mandatory prison terms, and various three-strikes statutes of question-
able effectiveness (see Dickey & Hollenhorst, 1998).
Matthew A. Robby assisted in the research for this article.
THE PRISON JOURNAL, Vol.82 No. 3, September 2002 386-407
© 2002 Sage Publications
386
As a result, prison and jail populations have grown rapidly. For example,
the U.S. prison population (state and federal) grew from 328,695 at the end of
1980 to 1,333,561 by midyear 1999, a 305% increase (Beck, 2000), with
concomitant increases in correctional costs at all levels of government (see
U.S. Department of Justice, 1998). Consequently, it became difficult for
many states to keep up with prison population growth and to provideenough
room for the constant flow of incoming inmates. This situation reached a cri-
sis point in 1994 when 39 states and three additional jurisdictions (Washing-
ton, D.C., Puerto Rico, Virgin Islands) were under court order to limit their
inmate populations and/or improve conditions in either the entire state sys-
tems or their major facilities (National Prison Project, 1995). Austin and
Irwin (2001) referred to this development as “America’s imprisonment
binge.”
Among others, these developments have created a fertile ground for the
entry of privatecorporations into the correctional “market.” The privatization
trend was facilitated by the strong ideological commitment of the Reagan
administration to the privatization of public services and the general ten-
dency of that regime to diminish governmentregulations. The importance of
this issue is reflected in the growing number of books and articles dealing
with this subject (e.g., Bowman, Hakim, & Seidenstadt, 1993; Easton, 1998;
Harding, 1997; James, Bottomley, Liebling, & Clare, 1997; Logan, 1990;
McDonald, 1990; Moyle, 1994; Robbins, 1989; Shichor, 1995).
This article deals with certain aspects of penal effectiveness as empha-
sized in the “new penology.” In this framework, our interest focuses on the
cost effectiveness and flexibility attributedto privatized correctional institu-
tions with a special emphasis on interjurisdictional transfer of prisoners in
the private prison industry to increase cost effectiveness and flexibility.
HISTORICAL PERUSAL OF PRIVATIZATION
Private involvement in the management and operation of jails and prisons
has always had an economic justification.The management of jails by private
individuals has a long history,especially in England, the American colonies,
and later in the United States. In England in the 13th century,there were local
jurisdictions in which private entrepreneurs were involved in the manage-
ment of jails. In some localities,
sheriffs hired working gaolers and threw the cost on the Exchequer,and in the
same period the crown sometimes relieved itself of such expenses, together
with the cost of maintenance, by requiring a subject to keep a gaol in return for
land, or by selling the right to do so for cash. To a growing extent, how-
Shichor, Sechrest/ PRIVATIZATION AND FLEXIBILITY 387

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT