Private investment with social benefits under uncertainty: The dark side of public financing

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12358
Date01 June 2020
AuthorAnne Stenger,Giuseppe Attanasi,Marco Buso,Kene Boun My
Published date01 June 2020
Received: 1 October 2017
|
Revised: 24 December 2018
|
Accepted: 27 December 2018
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12358
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Private investment with social benefits under
uncertainty: The dark side of public financing
Giuseppe Attanasi
1
|
Kene Boun My
2
|
Marco Buso
3
|
Anne Stenger
4
1
Université Côte dAzur, CNRS, GREDEG,
Nice, SophiaAntipolis, France
2
CNRS, BETA, Université de Strasbourg,
Strasbourg, France
3
Interuniversity Centre for Public Economics
(CRIEP), Interdepartmental Centre G. Levi
Cases for Energy, Economics and Technology,
University of Padova, Padua, Italy
4
BETA, INRA, Université de Strasbourg,
Strasbourg, France
Correspondence
Giuseppe Attanasi, GREDEG, CNRS,
Université Côte dAzur, CNRS, GREDEG
250, rue Albert Einstein, 06560 Nice
SophiaAntipolis, France.
Email: giuseppe.attanasi@unice.fr
Funding information
Agence Nationale de la Recherche, Grant/
Award Numbers: ANR "GrICRiS", ANR
ForWind012AGRO 0007
Abstract
We develop a gametheoretic model of privatepublic con-
tribution to a longterm project with sequential actions and
moral hazard. A private agent is one who is in charge of both
the financial contribution and the management effort, these
two actions entailing private costs and uncertain expost private
and social benefits. A public agent is one who decides the
amount of public funding to this quasipublic good, knowing
that the size and the probability of attaining a surplus ex post
depend on the private agents effort. We consider four public
funding scenarios: benefitsharing versus costsharing crossed
with exante versus exinterim government intervention. We
test our theoretical predictions by means of an experiment that
confirms the main result of the model: Costsharing public
intervention is more effective than benefitsharing in boosting
private financial contribution to the project. Furthermore, when
public intervention comes after private contribution (exinterim
government intervention), both publicfunding scenarios have a
negative impact on the private management effort. In our
model, the latter result is explained by the private agentshigh
degree of risk aversion. These results have policy implications
for strategic investments with longterm social consequences.
In deciding the optimal timing and method of the contribution,
governments should also consider the indirect effects on
agentslongterm management efforts.
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:769820. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet © 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
|
769
Editors note: This paper constitutes part of the two special issues of JPET Commemorating works of James Andreoni, Theodore Bergstrom, Larry
Blume, and Hal Varian
1
|
INTRODUCTION
In this paper, we provide a theoretical framework and a related laboratory experiment meant to investigate the
effect of public contribution on the private provision of a quasipublic good
1
that is characterized by uncertain
benefits and moral hazard. In general, markets for these goods are incomplete, so public intervention is considered to
be necessary to restore efficiency.
The specific quasipublic goods we are interested in are longterm projects that yield private and public
benefitsfor example, innovation activities that are pursued by private firms. Most of the existing research focuses
on assessing the shortterm impacts of public subsidies to these longterm projects. However, due to the lack of
reliable data, empirical studies can hardly measure public programsability to affect longterm outcomes and create
value for society. In addition, the behavioral effects of public interventions are difficult to assess from an empirical
point of view because of the difficulty in isolating and measuring private investorsbehavioral responses to such
interventions.
We claim that the controlled environment of a theorydriven laboratory experiment can help shed some light on
both issues. In particular, our main aim is to identify in an experiment the most efficient form and timing of
governments contribution to privately funded and managed longterm projects, which are characterized by moral
hazard and uncertain private and social benefits.
Developed countries allocate large portions of their budgets to largescale, longterm programs that (a) facilitate
the formation of longterm tangible assets (e.g., adaptation to climate change, and ecoinnovation technologies) and
intangible assets (e.g., education and research and development), and that (b) boost innovation and competitiveness
(European Commission, 2013; Olsen & Fearnley, 2014).
Many of these investments have wide public benefits because they generate significant returns for the
society as a whole by supporting essential services and improving living standards (see, e.g., EU program
Horizon 2020). However, such investments do not always attract private investors mainly for two reasons.
First, their private outcomes from these projects are characterized by a high level of uncertainty (e.g.,
Fankhauser, Smith, & Tol, 1999). Second, these projects typically imply social benefits that private agents do
not take into account.
2
In this view of privately provided public goods (Andreoni, 1988a), public funding can correct market failures,
giving private agents incentives for considering positive externalities for the society (Gonzalez, Jaumandreu,
& Pazo, 2005). However, public funding is primarily shortterm and focuses on the early stages of investment
(Borgström, Zachrisson, & Eckerberg, 2016) because the high level of uncertainty that characterizes
innovation activities makes both formal and informal contracts technically unfeasible (Tirole, 1999).
Therefore, the presence of incomplete contracting limits the possibility of regulation and control on expost
outcomes.
The governments limited ability to affect durable outcomes is confirmed by empirical studies that focus on the
effect of government contribution to innovative activities that are pursued by private firms. These empirical
analyses find no direct effect of public contribution on durable outcomes like workersand firmsproductivity or
the capacity to innovate (Cerqua & Pellegrini, 2014; de Blasio, Fantino, & Pellegrini, 2015; Lerner, 1999). Moreover,
the timing of the intervention (Georghiou, 1998) and private investorsexpectations about the level of contribution
1
Quasipublic goods are goods that benefit both public and private interests. They have the characteristics of both private and public goods, as they may
be seminonexcludable and/or seminonrival. Examples include roads, social infrastructures and innovations, parks, and public attractions.
2
Consider as an example the issue of adaptation to climate change. Many natural disasters that provoke economic damages are consequences of climate
change (e.g., drought, insect plagues, and windstorms). In the short term, interested private actors (e.g., farmers) should make financial investments to
start adaptation projects (e.g., implementation of new adequate infrastructures). Ecological restoration would be achieved only in the long term, through
efficient management of these projects. However, during the management stage private actors might underinvest in adaptation efforts. In fact, even if
these efforts do benefit first the agents who invest in adaptation, high uncertain effects of climate change in the future and understatement of adaptation
benefits for the society may lead to maladaptation.
770
|
ATTANASI ET AL.
(Gonzalez et al., 2005) are found to explain the expost (in)effectiveness of government support. A narrower strand
of literature focuses on the effect of public fundsnot just on the total level of private investment/innovation, but
on how investors behave during and/or after the project is implemented (behavioral additionality impact; see
Clarysse, Wright, & Mustar, 2009; Falk, 2007; Luukkonen, 2000). Empirical findings confirm that public incentives
can also have an indirect effect, either positive by facilitating exchanges through informal contracts that allow the
investor to learn the innovation process, or negative by creating a crowdingout effect on private innovation
investment (Falk, 2007; Luukkonen, 2000).
3
Our theoretical framework models this interaction between public intervention and private agentsbehavior in
the longterm project as a twostage game. In the first stage—“investment stage”—a representative private agent (a
consortium of private firms that is in charge of the negotiation process with the State) chooses the initial
investment, that is, the financial contribution to a quasipublic good (longterm project) whose public and private
outcomes are uncertain. We assume that these outcomes are perfectly correlated among them,
4
and positively
correlated with the amount of effort the private agent makes during the second stage of the project, namely the
management stage.Indeed, the private effort increases the probability that the project will yield high rather than
low private and social outcomes expost. To avoid confounding effects, we assume that this probability is
independent of the level of initial investment (private contribution to the quasipublic good). However, this level
increases the value of expost outcomes.
5
In line with the abovediscussed shortterm nature of public funding in longterm projects with social
benefits, we assume that the public agent is active only in the investment stage. During this stage, he or she
sets the amount of public funding to the project. Furthermore, while he or she may observe and always verify
the private agents initial investment, the level of effort is neither observable nor verifiable (moral hazard)
because of longterm and contingent outcomes. As a consequence, we assume that the public agent can
contribute in the short term only by providing monetary incentives that are based on the verifiable level of
investment. Considering this contractual constraint, we model four publicfunding scenarios: benefit sharing
versus costsharing, crossed with exante versus exinterim public intervention. The first variable describes
the type of public funding: The public agent may either grant a transfer that increases the private agents
marginal benefit from the investment, or sustain a fraction of the investment cost. The second variable
indicates the timing of this intervention in the investmentstage,thatis,beforeoraftertheprivateagentsets
the initial investment: in the former caseexante interventionthe level of investment is only verifiable,
while in the latterexinterim interventionit is also observable.
Our theoretical approach to the private provision of public goods is different from that followed by the
seminal papers of Andreoni (1988a) and Bergstrom, Blume, and Varian (1986). As is well known, they
consider publicgood games with multiple private agents facing a tradeoff between using their wealth to
consume a private good or contributing to a pure public good, with no nature uncertainty about private or
social outcomes. We instead study the private provision of quasipublic goods whose realizations are
3
In the case of intellectual property, public incentives can, paradoxically, lead to fewer healthimproving products (Heller & Eisenberg, 1998).
4
The assumption of a positive correlation between private and public benefits from the project better represents the kind of longterm projects analyzed
in this paper, especially when dealing with adaptation to climate change. Consider, as an example, the Noor Solar Power Station (Ouarzazate, Morocco). It
has been built to increase power generation from solar power in Morocco (construction began in May 2013, commercial operations began in June 2017).
Due to a publicprivate partnership contributing to the projectthe Moroccan Agency for Solar Energy and the Spanish consortium TSKAccionaSener
the public benefitsmitigation of greenhouse gas emissions and local environment impacts, green growth of local firms, improvement of the countrys
energy securityare strongly correlated with private onesrevenues from solar energy provision. We introduce the further assumption of perfect
correlation so as to nullify the discrepancy between exante equality and expost equality of private and public benefits, which might generate undesired
confounds in the behavior of agents with social preferences, for example, motivated by inequity aversion (see Sections 2.4 and 2.5).
5
Andreoni, Kuhn, and Samuelson (2018) analyze a twostage game where in the second stage a twoperiod prisoners dilemma is played, and in the first
stage the players can choose the allocation of the stakes across the two periods of the prisoners dilemma. They provide experimental evidence of a higher
joint payoff in the second stage if in the first one the stake allocation is endogenously chosen rather than randomly determined. Although in a completely
different setting, also in our twostage game the firststage choiceinitial investmentpositively affects the (privatepublic) joint payoff in the second
stage.
ATTANASI ET AL.
|
771

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT