Pricing schemes and market efficiency in private retirement systems

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12419
Date01 August 2020
AuthorMelati Nungsari,Marcela Parada‐Contzen,Sam Flanders
Published date01 August 2020
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:10411068. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet © 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
|
1041
Received: 24 April 2019
|
Accepted: 17 November 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12419
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Pricing schemes and market efficiency
in private retirement systems
Sam Flanders
1
|
Melati Nungsari
1
|
Marcela ParadaContzen
2
1
Department of Business, Asia School
of Business and MIT Sloan School of
Management, Sasana Kijang,
Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia
2
Departamento de Ingeniería Industrial,
Universidad de Concepción, Concepción,
Chile
Correspondence
Marcela ParadaContzen, Departamento
de Ingeniería Industrial, Universidad de
Concepción, Edmundo Larenas 219,
Concepción, Chile.
Email: mparadacontzen@gmail.com
Funding information
Fondo Nacional de Desarrollo Científico
y Tecnológico (Fondecyt),
Grant/Award Number: 3180155
Abstract
We study the effects of different pricing schemes on the
overall surplus in a privately managed retirement
system with multiple service providers and switching
costs. We develop a theoretical model based on the
Chilean retirement system and consider a repeated
auction for monopoly rights over new enrollees. We
consider a dynamic model solved by pension fund
administrators and by consumers. We compare three
different pricing schemes: (a) fees on contributions, (b)
fees on returns, and (c) a twopart tariff including an
auction over a guaranteed rate of return and allowing
the firm to keep a portion of returns generated above
this guaranteed rate. We also consider heterogeneity
across individuals where agents earn high or low wages
and highwage customers have proportionally lower
switching costs due to more costeffective access to
financial planning services. We find that auction
participants subsidize consumers. We also treat savings
as a durable good. In this case, pricing over returns
worsens the switching related inefficiencies just de-
scribed relative to pricing over contributions, despite the
better incentives it provides. These inefficiencies can be
resolved by allowing firms to price discriminate.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
In privately managed, defined contribution (DC) retirement systems, savings are usually
managed by firms known as pension fund administrators (PFAs). For their services, PFAs
charge a fee that might be defined as a share of contributions, benefits, or assets managed or as
an annual fixed amount (Creighton & Piggott, 2006). In this paper, we theoretically study the
efficiencymaximizing pricing scheme in a privately managed DC system. We consider the main
institutional settings of the Chilean system, which has served as an archetype for the
implementation of private systems around the world (Orszag & Stiglitz, 2001). We compare
total market surplus under three pricing schemes: (a) the current structure with fees on
contributions, (b) an alternative scheme with fees on returns, and finally, (c) a twopart tariff
(i.e., fee on contributions and returns) in which firms bid on a guaranteed rate of return.
Fee levels have been of continuous debate and concern policymakers (Barr & Diamond, 2016;
Tuesta, 2014). Countries in Latin America, together with the United States and transitioning
economies in Europe, have argued that fee levels are perceived to be too high (Tuesta, 2014).
Previous evidence shows that fees substantially reduce replacement rates (Modigliani &
Muralidhar, 2004) and pension returns (Bateman, Kingston, & Piggott, 2001) and may have
undesirable distributional impacts (Baily & Kirkegaard, 2008). Despite the evidence on the
effect of fees on pension outcomes, its effects on the efficacy of the retirement system have
received limited attention (Creighton & Piggott, 2006).
The architecture of DC systems varies across countries. Specifically, the fee structure
depends on the maturity of the financial sector and the PFA market upon introduction. For
example, in Latin America, because there was a concern that entry and competition were going
to be insufficient (Dobronogov & Murthi, 2005), because financial markets were still
undeveloped (Tuesta, 2014), and because it was not clear whether the industry would have
the initial capacity to charge fees on assets (Lasaga & Pollner, 2003), an upfront fee on
contributions was implemented. In Eastern Europe, where wellestablished Western European
financial companies are interested in operating in the market, there is a bigger presence of fees
on returns (Dobronogov & Murthi, 2005).
We focus on the Chilean retirement system. Thus, our contribution is directly related to the
Chilean model and policies within this system. The application of results could also consider
other very similar systems (e.g., Mexico and Peru). Because we treat the modeling assumptions
as generally as possible, the model could be extended to other systems. Our model considers
alternative pricing schemes and competitive settings with many firms competing for consumers,
as well as the context of duopolic markets. Many Latin American countries have implemented
structural reforms, similar to the Chilean one (e.g., Bolivia, Colombia, Dominican Republic, El
Salvador, Mexico, Peru, and others). There are also mixed models with public systems
coexisting with private systems with similar characteristics to the Chilean model (e.g.,
Argentina, Costa Rica, and Uruguay; MesaLago, 2008). Mixed models with a private portion
that shared features with the Chilean system are the models that have been most extended
outside of Latin America, mostly in Eastern Europe (e.g., Hungary, Poland, Czech Republic,
Latvia, Bulgaria, Croatia, and Estonia; MesaLago & Hohnerlein, 2002). Developed countries
such as the United States have also discussed the implementation of such a system (Joubert,
2015; Joubert & Todd, 2016).
A novelty of this paper is that we explicitly model the auction dynamics for monopoly
rights, implemented in Chile, to new enrollees and incorporate switching costs for consumers
to switch between PFAs (both homogenous and heterogeneous switching costs). Auctions to
assign monopoly rights over enrollees have been recommended for increasing competition
and decreasing fees (Fischer, González, & Serra, 2006; Kurach, Kusmierczyk, & Papla, 2017).
After the Chilean experience, auctions were also implemented in Peru and have received
the attention of policymakers in Mexico, Australia, New Zealand, and Poland (Chomik &
Piggott, 2015; Heuser, Kwok, Snethlage, & Watts, 2015; Kurach, 2019; Kurach et al., 2017;
1042
|
FLANDERS ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT