Pricing Forward Skew Dependent Derivatives. Multifactor Versus Single‐Factor Stochastic Volatility Models

AuthorJacinto Marabel Romo
Date01 February 2014
Published date01 February 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/fut.21611
PRICING FORWARD SKEW DEPENDENT
DERIVATIVES.MULTIFACTOR VERSUS
SINGLEFACTOR STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY MODELS
JACINTO MARABEL ROMO*
Empirical evidence shows that, in equity options markets, the slope of the skew is largely
independent of the volatility level. Singlefactor stochastic volatility models are not exible
enough to account for the stochastic behavior of the skew. On the other hand, multifactor
stochastic volatility models are able to account for the existence of stochastic skew. Thisstudy
studies the effects of introducing stochastic skew in the valuation of forward skew dependent
exotic options. In particular, I consider cliquet, as well as reverse cliquet structures. The study
also derives a semiclosedform solution for the price of forwardstart options under the
multifactor stochastic specication. The empirical results indicate that the consideration of
additional volatility factors in the context of stochastic volatility models allows us to generate
more exible smile patterns. This additional exibility has a relevant impact on the valuation of
forward skew dependent derivatives. In this sense, this study shows that similar calibrations
of single factor and multifactor stochastic volatility models to the current market prices of
plain vanilla options can lead to important discrepancies in the pricing of exotic forward
skew dependent derivatives such as regular cliquet structures and reverse cliquet options.
© 2013 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 34:124144, 2014
1. INTRODUCTION
The assumptions of the BlackScholes (1973) model imply that the implied volatility surface
should be at and static. But since the stock market crash on October 1987, equity options
markets have been characterized by a persistent negative dependence of implied volatility with
respect to the strike price. This negative dependence is known as the implied volatility skew.
On the other hand, for foreign currencies outofthemoney options usually exhibit higher
implied volatilities than atthemoney options. This effect is known as the volatility smile.
Furthermore, the implied volatility surface displays term structure and varies stochastically
through time generating vega risk.
There are a number of models that have been proposed to deal with these stylized facts.
Local volatility models postulate that the instantaneous volatility (called local volatility) is a
deterministic function of the underlying asset price and time. Within this group we have the
works of Dupire (1994), Derman and Kani (1994), or Rubinstein (1994). Merton (1976),
among others, incorporates the possibility of jumps in the stochastic process for the
underlying asset price. This feature is consistent with the behavior of nancial assets and
Jacinto Marabel Romo is an Equity Derivatives Trader, BBVA and a researcher, University Institute for
Economic and Social Analysis, University of Alcalá, Alcalá de Henares, Madrid, Spain. The content of this
paper represents the authors personal opinion and does not reect the views of BBVA.
*Correspondence author, Vía de los Poblados s/n, 28033 Madrid, Spain. Tel: þ34915379985, Fax: þ34
915370913. email: jacinto.marabel@bbva.com
Received September 2012; Accepted January 2013
The Journal of Futures Markets, Vol. 34, No. 2, 124144 (2014)
© 2013 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Published online 25 February 2013 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com).
DOI: 10.1002/fut.21611
generates implied volatility skew. The main problem with these models is that when the jump
size is stochastic and it has a continuous distribution, the model becomes incomplete. Madan
and Milne (1991) and Carr, Geman, Madan, and Yor (2003), among others, consider Lévy
processbased models. On the other hand, stochastic volatility models leave the constant
instantaneous volatility assumption of the BlackScholes (1973) model and assume that
volatility follows a stochastic process possibly correlated with the process for the stock price.
Some examples of this approach can be found in Hull and White (1987) and Hagan, Kumar,
Lesniewski, and Woodward (2002), among others. Stochastic volatility models explain the
basic shapes of smile patterns and they also allow for more realistic theories of the term
structure of implied volatility (Lewis, 2000). One of the most celebrated singlefactor
stochastic volatility models is the Heston (1993) model. The main reason is that it allows the
computation of European option prices quite efciently. One of the parameters of the model is
the correlation between the underlying asset return and its instantaneous variance. A negative
value for this parameter generates implied volatility skew. But the fact that, in singlefactor
stochastic volatility models, this correlation is constant implies that the model is not exible
enough to account for the stochastic behavior of the skew observed in options markets (see,
e.g., Christoffersen, Heston, & Jacobs, 2009).
A number of models have been proposed to extend the Heston (1993) model in order to
account for the stylized facts that the model is not able to consider. In particular,
Christoffersen et al. (2009) extend the original Heston (1993) framework to generate a two
factor stochastic volatility model built upon the square root process. This model accounts for
stochastic correlation between the asset return and its instantaneous variance. Another
extension to the Heston (1993) stochastic volatility model is proposed by da Fonseca,
Grasselli, & Tebaldi (2008). These authors consider a Wishart specication to introduce a
correlation structure between the single asset noise and the volatility factors. This model is
also able to account for stochastic correlation between the asset return and its instantaneous
variance and, hence, is able to generate stochastic skew.
Note that forward skews and volatility of volatility, are outputs in stochastic volatility
models and cannot be adjusted to reproduce market observables. On the other hand, the local
stochastic volatility model combines the local volatility model, to t the vanilla surface, and the
stochastic volatility model, to model forward skews (see, e.g., Jex, Henderson, & Wang, 1999;
Lipton, 2002; or Ren, Madan, & Qian, 2008). One advantage of the local stochastic volatility
(LSV) model is that it allows for an exact calibration to the market implied volatility surface as
opposite to the stochastic volatility bestt calibration. In this sense, since within the LSV
specication the vanilla surface is matched by construction, we have the freedom to specify
the parameters of the stochastic volatility process to match either historical data or market
data for nonvanilla options. LSV models became popular in foreign exchange markets.
However, in equity markets they are less popular. The reason may be that one disadvantage of
LSV specications is their tendency to misprice forward volatility products, such as cliquets,
as pointed out by Karasinski and Sepp (2012). In this sense, these authors propose a model
that is able to generate steeper forward skews.
Christoffersen et al. (2009) show that their model provides better empirical t than the
Heston (1993) model to the market price of European options using multiple crosssection
data corresponding to the Standard and Poors 500 equity index. The main reason is that, in
equity options markets, the slope of the skew is largely independent of the volatility level
(Derman, 1999). A singlefactor stochastic volatility model can generate steep skew or at
skew at a given volatility level but cannot generate both for a given parameterization. Note
that in a purely crosssectional analysis this is not a problem since we can calibrate different
parameters levels for the onefactor model to account for the timevarying nature of the
crosssection. In this sense, it is important to consider how practitioners use the models.
Forward Skew Dependent Derivatives and Stochastic Volatility 125

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT