Price and quality competition with quality positions

Date01 March 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12229
Published date01 March 2018
Received: 31 March 2016 Revised: 27 July 2017 Accepted: 31 August 2017
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12229
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Price and quality competition with quality positions
Shogo Kurokawa1Nobuo Matsubayashi2
1Department of Administration Engineering,
Faculty of Science and Technology,Keio
University,Yokohama, Japan (Email:
scarletcurio@gmail.com)
2Department of Administration Engineering,
Faculty of Science and Technology,Keio
University,Yokohama, Japan (Email:
nobuo-m@pa2.so-net.ne.jp)
Abstract
In this study, we investigate price and quality decisions in a duopoly in the presence
of firms’ quality positions , which are determined by the quality levels of their exist-
ing core products. Into a standard model of vertical differentiation, we incorporate
a “repositioning cost” that is proportional to the quality differences between firms’
current and new products. By varying the levels of quality positions, we analyze the
impact of this cost on the equilibrium outcomes. Our results show that the presence of
repositioning costs restricts firms’ abilities to improve profitability and differentiate
themselves vertically. As a result, a high-positioned firm does not necessarily have a
competitive advantage overa low-positioned firm, even if the former offers a superior
new product in equilibrium. In addition, if a low-positioned firm is significantly cost-
efficient compared with its rival with regard to repositioning, then that firm can earn
higher profits than those of a high-positioned firm by strategically offering its low-
end product. These results contrast sharply with those based on the standard vertical
differentiation model.
1INTRODUCTION
In many industries, developing new products is one of a firm's most important activities. Past cases have shown that a firm's
sustainability is determined by whether it can develop new products that are adopted successfully by the market. On the other
hand, entering foreign markets, particularly in emerging countries, is another attractive option for firms in advanced countries.
From manufacturers to service providers, there are many examples of firms that haveexpanded their business to other countr ies.
Regardless of whether incumbent firms in the real world develop new products for their home markets or modify existing
products for foreign markets, their activities are affected by their capabilities, including their core technology, sales skills, and
operational know-how. Successfully utilizing these resources to develop new products or modify existing ones improves their
profitability (Barney, 1991). Specifically, when a firm introduces a new product with the same level of quality as its existing
product, it only incurs setup costs related to the introduction of the new product. Otherwise, firms must incur some additional
cost, which depends heavily on their current capabilities. The extent of this cost is determined by the degree of “repositioning”
that firms must undertake, which is based on the difference in quality between its current and new products. Therefore, we refer
to this type of cost as a “repositioning cost.”
Repositioning costs are present in real-world businesses. For example, Louis Vuitton persists in introducing high-end clothes
and, thus, never offers low-priced products such as those provided by fast fashion chains (e.g., H&M). This fact reflects that
incumbent firms must incur significant costs when changing their product positioning, regardless of whether they increase or
decrease the quality of their products. The following costs arise from repositioning activities: (1) the costs of introducing new
production facilities, (2) educational expenses to acquire know-how, (3) the costs of developing new distribution networks, (4)
marketing costs to acquire customers in new markets, and (5) advertising costs to make consumers aware of the new position.
Note that even if the quality of a new productis lower than that of the existing product, the firm must incur positive repositioning
costs, primarily to maintain its reputation.
J Econ Manage Strat. 2018;27:71–81. © 2017 WileyPeriodicals, Inc. 71wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT