Preferred provider organizations: An antitrust perspective

AuthorRobert E. Youle,Paul C. Daw
Date01 June 1984
Published date01 June 1984
DOI10.1177/0003603X8402900206
Subject MatterArticle
The Antitrust Bulletin/Summer 1984
Preferred provider organizations:
an antitrust perspective
BY ROBERT E. YOULE*
and
PAUL C. DAW**
301
••
I.
Introduction'
Preferred provider organizations (PPOs) have attracted substan-
tial interest in recent months as a strategy to promote the efficient
purchase
of
health care services. Recent publications indicate that
84 hospitals have already formed or joined PPOs, an additional
700 hospitals are considering
PPO
involvement,' and at least 160
PPOs
are currently doing business in California alone.' PPOs
have also engaged the attention
of
physician groups, third-party
payors, labor unions, private businesses, health care coalitions,
and independent entrepreneurs. The
PPO
concept has been en-
dorsed by state legislatures that have recognized its potential to
Member, Sherman &Howard, Denver, Colorado.
Associate, Sherman &Howard, Denver, Colorado.
IThe authors gratefully acknowledge
the
research assistance
of
Eric R. Decator.
2See Schroer &Taylor, A Survey
of
Preferred Provider Organiza-
tions,
HOSPITALS
85 (Mar. 16, 1984). These
data
were compiled in the
course
of
a survey initiated in September 1982.
3See Rundle, PPOs: The New Buzzword to Learn,
BUSINESS
INSURANCE
3 (May 30, 1983).
~:'
1984 by Federal Legal Publications, Inc.
302 The antitrust bulletin
increase competition in the health care industry
and
to reduce
total health expenditures.'
As has been the case with other innovative forms
of
health
care delivery, the future
of
PPOs
is clouded to some degree by
legal uncertainties. Perhaps most threatening are the antitrust
risks that face
PPOs.
This article will attempt to describe the
basic characteristics
of
PPOs, outline the jurisdictional and
substantive antitrust issues most likely to confront them, and
suggest organizational and operational methods
of
reducing a
PPO's
antitrust exposure. Our general thesis is that
PPOs
present
aunique mechanism by which competition in the health care
industry can be increased, and that if properly structured and
operated, their business should not be unduly constrained by the
antitrust laws.
II. Characteristics
of
PPOs
The term "preferred provider organization" refers to a con-
cept
and
not a specific kind
of
entity.' Among other things, a
PPO
can be an independent organization, acombination
of
otherwise unrelated health care providers, an insurance company
affiliate, or merely a contractual relationship.
PPOs
are intermediary organizations
that
arrange for third-
party
payors to purchase health care services for their subscribers
from selected providers, including hospitals and physicians." A
PPO
typically contracts with a limited number
of
providers
(physicians, hospitals, allied health care professionals, or some
4See generally American Hospital Association, State Regulation
of
Preferred Provider Organizations: A Survey
of
State Statutes (Mar.
1984).
5See Lundy &Blacker, Preferred Provider Organizations: The
Latest Response to Health Care
Competition-An
Overview,
HEALTHCARE
FINANCIAL
MANAGEMENT
(June 1983).
6Stromberg, Duncheon &Goldman, PPOs and the Antitrust
Laws,
HOSPITALS
65 (Oct. 16, 1983).
An
antitrust perspective 303
combination
of
the three) who agree to provide services in
consideration for payment by the
PPO
on a fee-for-service basis.
The payment rate is typically less than the provider's usual and
customary fee. In exchange for the discounted fee, the
PPO
provides economic incentives to its subscribers to use the partici-
pating or preferred providers. This incentive usually consists
of
payment
of
the subscriber's entire health care charge if a pre-
ferred provider is used, but a lesser reimbursement if the sub-
scriber uses a nonparticipating provider.
In essence, then, a
PPO
is a mechanism that delivers health
care services at preferred rates to subscribers who are given
incentives to utilize providers under contract with the
PPO.
Viewed in this light, a
PPO
is a form
of
vertical integration.
It
combines, or at least connects, the underwriting
of
risk with the
delivery
of
health care services. As such, it offers the usual
advantages of such integration, and its attractiveness to payors,
subscribers, and providers is manifest.
By creating incentives for subscribers to patronize preferred
providers, the
PPO
presents an attractive source of patient
volume to health care providers. This, in turn, should enable
providers to realize economies
of
scale. Furthermore,
PPOs
typically promise to pay claims promptly, thereby reducing the
provider's risk
of
uncollectible accounts and shortening the pe-
riod in which his bill remains unpaid.
PPO
affiliation may also
appeal to the provider as a defensive measure, useful in curbing
the inroads
of
health maintenance organizations (HMOs), com-
peting providers aligned with other PPOs, and so forth.
From
the payor's standpoint, a
PPO
provides aguaranteed
"supply"
of
health care services at predetermined rates. In this
manner, the payor can predict its costs and establish reasonably
stable premiums. The payor can also use the
PPO
mechanism to
exert pressure on providers for discounted rates in exchange for
increases in volume.' Moreover, the payor can attain cost efficien-
7Various health policy experts believe that PPOs and PPO-like
arrangements will stimulate price competition in the health services
market by channeling subscriber patronage to cost-effective provider

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT