Preferences, entry, and market structure

Date01 November 2016
Published date01 November 2016
AuthorPaolo Bertoletti,Federico Etro
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12155
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.47, No. 4, Winter 2016
pp. 792–821
Preferences, entry, and market structure
Paolo Bertoletti
and
Federico Etro∗∗
We provide a unified approach to imperfect (monopolistic, Bertrand, and Cournot) competition
when preferences are symmetric over a finite but endogenous number of goods. Markups depend
on the Morishima elasticity of substitution and on the number of varieties. The comparative
statics of free-entry equilibria is examined, establishing the conditions formarkup neutrality with
respect to income, market size, and productivity. We compare endogenous and optimal market
structures for severalnon-CES examples. With a generalized linear direct utility, the markupcan
be constant and optimal under monopolistic competition, and nonmonotonic in the number of
firms under Bertrand or Cournot competition.
1. Introduction
To understand how demand and supply fundamentals affect the structure of a market,
namely, how many firms are active in it, how much they produce, and at which markup they
sell, is a basic concern of economic theory. This important issue arises in the partial equilibrium
analysis of industrial organization, as well as in general equilibrium applications, for instance,
in international trade and macroeconomics.1However, most of the modern theory of imperfect
competition in markets with product differentiation is based on a few, specific microfoundations
of the demand side. Models of monopolistic competition are usually based on CES preferences
University of Pavia; paolo.bertoletti@unipv.it.
∗∗University of Venice Ca’ Foscari; federico.etro@unive.it.
We are very grateful to Giuseppe Savar´
e for fundamental clarifications on the properties of symmetric functions, but of
course, the usual disclaimer applies. We also thank Giacomo Corneo, Paolo Epifani, Massimo Filippini, Atsushi Kajii,
Giorgio Rampa, Lorenza Rossi, Ina Simonovska, Kresimir Zigic, two anonymous referees, and especially the Editor,
Mark Armstrong, for useful comments. Seminar participants at the International Workshop on Global Competition
and Innovation (Awaji, Japan, March 1, 2014), Free University of Berlin, Kyoto University, Yonsei University (Seoul),
Padova University, Pavia University, University of Italian Swiss (Lugano), Delhi School of Economics, and the 2015
SAET conference at the University of Cambridge (UK) provided insightful comments. Further results can be found in
the Working Paper version with the title, “A General Theor y of Endogenous Market Structures” (DEM W.P. no. 81,
University of Pavia, Dept. of Economics and Management, June 2014).
1There is a wide empirical literature pointing out that markups are affected by the number of consumers, their
income, and productivity shocks. For recent examples, see Campbell and Hopenhayn (2005) on competition effects
in industrial organization, Simonovska (2015) on pricing to market in trade, and Nekarda and Ramey (2013) on the
cyclicality of markups in macroeconomics.
792 C2016, The RAND Corporation.
BERTOLETTI AND ETRO / 793
or on separable direct utilities as in Dixit and Stiglitz (D-S, 1977) or on quasilinear preferences
as in Spence (1976), and more recently Melitz and Ottaviano (2008), and Anderson, Erkal,
and Piccinin (2012).2As is well known, strategic interactions `
alaCournot or Ber trand add a
competitive element to the equilibrium of monopolistic competition, but also their analysis has
been usually limited to a few microfounded examples. Other cases analyzed in the literature
include those of homothetic preferences (Benassy,1996; Feenstra, 2003 and 2014; D’Aspremont,
Dos Santos Ferreira, and Gerard-Varet, 2007) and of separable indirect utilities (Bertoletti and
Etro, 2014). Beyond these cases, little is known about how preferences shape competition and
the incentives to enter a market.
In this work, we provide a first step to characterize, under a general microfoundation,
the basic elements of an endogenous market structure: the number of active firms and the
quantity/price strategies adopted by them. We endogenize consumer behavior, entry choices, and
market strategies, but wetake as a given the technological conditions and the mode of competition,
which we assume to be either monopolistic competition `
a la Chamberlin, Bertrand competition in
prices, or Cournot competition in quantities. Although this is typical of trade and macroeconomic
applications, we leave for future research the extension to additional interesting aspects of firm
behavior,such as the endogenous determination of technology through Research and Development
(R&D) activity (Sutton, 1991) and of the mode of competition (see D’Aspremont, Dos Santos
Ferreira, and Gerard-Varet, 2007).
Our purpose is to analyze the three main forms of competition when consumers are endowed
with general (nonseparable) preferences that are symmetric3over a largenumber of differentiated
goods, of which only some are endogenouslyprovided. Westar t proposing a generalized definition
of monopolistic competition that applies to all cases with a large but finite number of goods.
Exploiting the properties of symmetric preferences, we show that the relevant demand elasticity
is provided by the so-called Morishima elasticity of substitution (as defined in Blackorby and
Russell, 1981),4and can be computed directly from the utility function. We also show how the
markups relevant in Bertrand and Cournot symmetric equilibria depend on the same elasticity and
on the number of varieties actually provided. These results confirm that the difference between
the true demand elasticity and that perceived by firms under our definition of monopolistic
competition is indeed negligible when the number of goods is large enough.5On this basis,
we characterize the implications of free entry and the comparative statics of the associated
endogenous market structure. To illustrate how to derive imperfect competition equilibria, we
reconsider a variety of preferences used in the literature on monopolistic competition, such as
additive preferences or examples of homothetic preferences.6In addition, we provide the first
characterization of the equilibria under the so-called generalized linear direct utility proposed by
Diewert (1971), and under quadratic utilities that are neither homothetic nor additive.7Following
Feenstra (2003), we account for changes in the functional form representing preferences due to
changes in the number of available goods.
2The case of additively separable preferences has been recently reconsidered by Zhelobodko et al. (2012) and
Bertoletti and Epifani (2014). Many results are also known for quasilinear preferences with an outside good (Vives,
1999), but this assumption has the cost of eliminating any mechanism through which income directly affectsdemand.
3In the economics of product differentiation, the assumption of symmetric preferences is the hallmark of the
“Chamberlinian paradigm,” as first formalized by D-S (1977).
4Notice that in the general case of preferences defined over more than two goods, there are different ways of
defining the elasticity of substitution (see Blackorby and Russell, 1989).
5This is known in models based on additive preferences: see, for instance, Yang and Heijdra (1993) and Bertoletti
and Epifani (2014). We showthat it holds in all models with symmetric preferences.
6In particular, we consider translog preferences and the so-called generalized Leontief preferences: these belong
to the so-called “quadratic mean of order r” (QMOR) expenditure functions recently reexamined byFeenstra (2014).
7Although we are not aware of an earlier use of the quadratic indirect utility considered here, the quadratic direct
utility is derived bythe quasilinear preferences of Melitz and Ottaviano (2008), eliminating the outside good and has been
used elsewhere under monopolistic competition.
C
The RAND Corporation 2016.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT