Son Preference, Number of Children, Education and Occupational Choice in Rural Nepal

AuthorMagnus Hatlebakk
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12237
Published date01 February 2017
Date01 February 2017
Son Preference, Number of Children, Education and
Occupational Choice in Rural Nepal
Magnus Hatlebakk*
Abstract
A unique family survey was conducted in Nepal to investigate the economic consequences of having a
first-born girl. Women have more children, but we find no causal effect of number of children on
economic outcomes, but independently of the number of children there is a positive effect on boys’
education of having a first-born sister, who presumably takes care of household work so the boys can
focus on school. This indicates a stronger son preference in Nepal than that found in studies from
neighboring countries.
1. Introduction
For South Asia it is well known that son preference explains selective abortion of
girls (at least in India), or additional children if the first born turns out to be a girl.
1
We focus on the potential costs of having too many children in Nepal, where, as we
shall see, abortion of girls is still not a problem. We investigate whether son
preference leads to more children and thus less investment in each child. Inspired
by the literature we started out with the random gender of the first born as an
exogenous instrument for number of children, but we discovered that it is not the
number of children that matters for the investments in each child, it is rather the
instrument itself that has a direct and positive effect, in contrast to the potential
negative effect of number of children. If the first born is a girl, then later-born boys
receive better education. This finding, which has no parallel in the literature as far
as we know, is reported together with a number of robustness checks and analysis
of additional economic outcomes.
We combine two strands of literature in a unified framework. Angrist and Evans
(1998) is the seminal contribution to the literature where the gender of first-born
children is used as an instrument for the number of children. Their work led to an
extensive literature focusing on the effect of family size on female labor supply, see
for example Cruces and Galiani (2007) on data from Mexico and Argentina, and
Daouli et al. (2009) on Greece. Within this strand there is a more limited literature
that looks at other economic outcomes, including Gupta and Dubey (2006) on
poverty in India. Our focus is on education, and similarly to us, most studies find
no causal effect of number of children on children’s education, although there are
*Hatlebakk: Chr. Michelsen Institute (CMI), P.O. Box 6033, 5892, Bergen, Norway. Tel: +47-4793-8000;
Fax: +47-4793-8001; E-mail: magnus.hatlebakk@cmi.no. The research is part of a joint project with
Yogendra Gurung and Bal Kumar KC, IPDS in Kathmandu. The research is funded by the Research
Council of Norway through the EconPop program that, in turn, is part of the international PopPov
network. Thanks go to Anjushree Pradhan from New Era who advised on the survey, as well as Sachin
Shrestha, also New Era, who supervised the survey together with us. Thanks also go to Arild Aakvik and
Vincent Somville for useful comments and suggestions.
Review of Development Economics, 21(1), 1–20, 2017
DOI:10.1111/rode.12237
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
two recent studies that find a negative effect by Ponczek and Souza (2012) and
Kugler and Kumar (2015). Ponczek and Souza also have a good review of this
literature.
Within this strand of the literature the seminal theoretical model of the link
between number of children and investments in each child is due to Becker (1960,
see his footnote 10 for the formal model). Becker describes a qualityquantity
trade-off in preferences where the two variables are simultaneously determined,
subject to the costs of raising and educating children. If a women for some reason
(and we focus on the random event that she has a girl first) decides to have more
children, she may at the same time decide to compensate by investing less in each
child, but that would be a causal effect of having a girl first on both quality and
quantity of children. When we attempt below to identify a causal effect of number
of children on their education, then we implicitly assume a recursive structure
where the women first observe the gender of the first born, then decide on the
number of children and finally decide on their education. This is not an unlikely
sequence of events, but as said, we do not find a significant effect in the last part of
the chain of decisions, only the first effect of the gender of the first born on number
of children is significant. This may reflect that a first-born girl simultaneously affects
both the number of children and their education, but we focus below on a more
direct interpretation of the finding, as it is likely that the first-born girl takes care of
household work so that her brothers can focus on school. This interpretation is
supported by Edmonds’ (2006) analysis of time use among children in Nepal where
he, in fact, finds that older girls work more than their brothers and even more if
they have additional younger siblings.
The second strand of the literature applies birth order and gender as direct
explanatory variables. A robust finding from poor countries seems to be that
siblings of first-born girls receive more education than others. We have, however,
an even more specific finding in our data, as only male siblings receive more
education if the first born is a girl. We thus find a stronger son preference, since
only boys benefit, than in similar studies from neighboring countries where later-
born children of both gender benefit; see Sawada and Lokshin (2009) on Pakistan,
and Ota and Moffatt (2007) on India. This male only effect is the main contribution
of the paper. There is a related literature where the focus is only on birth order
and a possible interaction with own gender (but without looking at the gender of
the siblings), see for example Ejrnæs and P
ortner (2004) who find that later-born
boys (in the Philippines) spend more time in school, and Emerson and Souza
(2008) who find that daughters (in Brazil) who are first born are less likely to go to
school than later-born daughters.
We consider it value added to use data from Nepal, where the literature on son
preference is limited, but see Koolwal (2007) who analyzes the link between son
preference and child labor in Nepal. There is, however, a related literature on son
preference elsewhere, in particular Basu and de Jong (2010) on son preferences in
India, Das Gupta et al. (2003) on determinants of son preference in China, India
and South Korea, and Edlund and Lee (2009) on theory and evidence for son
preference in South Korea.
The fact that Nepali women have more children if the first born is a girl is well
knownsee for example Gudbrandsen (2013), who uses the 2006 demographic and
health survey (DHS).
2
The DHS data has, however, only limited information on
economic outcomes. An alternative is the Nepal Living Standards Surveys (NLSS,
1995, 2003, 2010), which are of high quality and contain information on a number
2Magnus Hatlebakk
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT