Son preference and the demographic transition

Published date01 February 2022
AuthorAnna‐Maria Aksan
Date01 February 2022
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12831
32
|
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rode Rev Dev Econ. 2022;26:32–56.
© 2021 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Received: 10 June 2021 
|
Revised: 26 August 2021 
|
Accepted: 31 August 2021
DOI: 10.1111/rode.12831
REGULAR ARTICLE
Son preference and the demographic transition
Anna- MariaAksan
Department of Economics, DMH 326, 
Fairfield University, Fairfield, CT, USA
Correspondence
Anna- Maria Aksan, Department 
of Economics, DMH 326, Fairfield 
University, 1073 North Benson Road, 
Fairfield, CT 06824- 5195, USA.
Email: aaksan@fairfield.edu
Abstract
In a general equilibrium model of fertility with higher 
economic returns to sons relative to daughters, parents 
choose overall fertility and the gender composition of 
their children. Son preference is partially endogenized to 
reflect how relative scarcity of females raises their value 
even while social norms and lack of economic opportu-
nities lessen their value. These competing factors lead to 
an oscillating sex ratio. Model simulations demonstrate 
that son preference increases fertility, but that sex selec-
tion reduces fertility in the presence of son preference. 
The results suggest that effectively banning sex- selective 
abortions in places such as India, which has struggled 
to enforce its existing ban on the practice, is insufficient 
and may have unintended consequences such as slow-
ing fertility decline, reducing quality investment in girls, 
and slowing human capital accumulation and economic 
growth. Improving economic opportunities for women 
will increase the value placed on daughters, thereby im-
proving the sex ratio and human capital investment in 
all children.
KEYWORDS
demographic transition, sex selection, son preference, quantity– 
quality tradeoff
JEL CLASSIFICATION
J11; J13; J16
|
33
AKSAN
|
INTRODUCTION
Since 1980 India’s child mortality rate (CMR) fell by 71%, from 166 deaths per 1,000 live births to 
47.7 in 2015, while the total fertility rate (TFR) declined from 4.8 to 2.4 children per woman. In 
China the CMR fell by 82%, from 61 deaths per 1,000 live births to 10.7 in 2015, while the TFR 
declined from 2.6 to 1.6 (World Development Indicators, 2017). Yet this apparent progress is ob-
scured by a severe sex ratio imbalance in both countries. The most recent Indian census data of
2011 indicate that the current sex ratio at birth (SRB) was 1.12 males per female, up from 1.10 in 
2001, and has been estimated to be as high as 1.3– 1.5 in some regions of the country (Guilmoto, 
2009; Rajan et al., 2017). In China the SRB rose from 1.09 in 1982 to 1.18 in 2012 (UNICEF, 
2017). These imbalances are in large part attributed to the technologically aided sex- selective 
termination of pregnancies, even though the practice has been outlawed in both countries. We 
examine theoretically the potential consequences for the well- being of both boys and girls, the 
demographic transition, and economic growth.
A preference for sons arises from economic considerations and cultural norms (Mayer, 1999). 
Stronger patrilocal and patrilineal traditions coincide with a higher sex ratio in parts of Asia, the 
Middle East and North Africa (Basu, 1999; Jayachandran, 2015). In the absence of social security 
programs and an efficient financial system by which to save for old age, parents rely on their 
children to care for them. In India, China, and South Korea traditionally the son supports his 
parents when they age, inherits the property, and continues the family line (Chung & Das Gupta, 
2007; Jayachandran, 2015). Hindu and Confucian traditions emphasize the son’s imperative role 
in caring for his parents in old age and in their afterlife (Bhaskar, 2011; Chung & Das Gupta, 
2007; Jayachandran, 2015). In contrast, raising a daughter is considered akin to “watering your 
neighbor’s garden" since she eventually moves in with her husband’s family and cares for his 
parents (Arnold et al., 1998; Guilmoto, 2009). Moreover, dowries in South Asia have increased in 
real value over time and are a financial burden on the daughter’s family (Basu, 1999).
The practice of sex- selective abortion magnifies the demographic effects of more traditional 
methods of gender control, specifically stopping behavior whereby parents have children until 
the desired number of sons is born, and even infanticide or neglect of newborn daughters 
(Bongaarts, 2013). Rapid increases in the SRB have followed geographical patterns of ultrasound 
technology diffusion, particularly throughout the 1980s in India, South Korea, and China. While 
South Korea’s sex ratio has returned to normal since its peak of 1.15 in the early 1990s, India 
remains less economically developed and its SRB continues to worsen (Guilmoto, 2009; Rajan 
et al., 2017). As India modernizes and its demographic transition proceeds, in many regions par-
ents prefer to have fewer children, potentially intensifying the sex ratio imbalance (Das Gupta & 
Bhat, 1997; Dharmalingam et al., 2014; Guilmoto, 2009). Parents can effectively choose to have 
more sons and fewer daughters. China’s experience has been similar, although some of its fertil-
ity decline can be attributed to state- mandated restrictions on family size via the so- called “one- 
child policy.” Falling fertility combined with son preference led to rapid increases in SRBs during 
the 1990s in the South Caucasus, reaching 1.17 in Azerbaijan in 2002, 1.19 in Georgia in 1998, 
and 1.16 in Armenia in 2001 (Guilmoto, 2009).
Theoretically, falling desired fertility could improve sex ratios if the ideal number of sons 
declines more quickly than desired fertility (Das Gupta & Bhat, 1997). For example, Hindus con-
sider it sacramental to give away one daughter in marriage, while sons, on the other hand, are 
perceived as productive assets (Bhat & Zavier, 2003). Thus as ideal family size declines, the ideal 
number of daughters changes little, while the ideal number of sons changes more. Bongaarts 
(2013) illustrates a positive relationship between desired fertility and son preference (i.e. desired

Get this document and AI-powered insights with a free trial of vLex and Vincent AI

Get Started for Free

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT