Predatory Pricing and the Meaning of Intent

Date01 June 1993
AuthorH.E. Frech,William S. Comanor
DOI10.1177/0003603X9303800202
Published date01 June 1993
Subject MatterArticle
The Antitrust Bulletin/Summer 1993
Predatory pricing and the
meaning
of
intent
BY WILLIAM S. COMANOR· and H.E. FRECH
III·
I.
Introduction
293
In a recent decision,1Judge Frank Easterbrook boldly stated that
judges and juries should ignore questions
of
intent in antitrust
cases dealing with predatory conduct. Writing for a unanimous
three-judge panel, Easterbrook argued that a firm's intent to harm
its competitors is indistinguishable from its intent to compete. As
a result, looking only for the intent to harm competitors invites
juries to penalize hard competition. We agree, but his opinion
went further.
It
concluded: "we now hold that intent is not a basis
for liability (or a ground for inferring the existence
of
such a
basis) in a predatory pricing case under the Sherman Act.'? This is
Professor, Department of Economics, University of California,
Santa Barbara.
AUTIIORS' NOTE: We are grateful to Frank Easterbrook, Clement Krouse,
M. Bruce Johnson and Steve De Canio for helpful comments on earlier
drafts
of
this article.
A.A. Poultry Farms, Inc. v, Rose Acre Farms, Inc., 881 F.2d 1396
(7th Cir. 1989).
2
Id.at61,717.
(/) 1993 by Federal Legal Publlcations, Inc.
294 : The antitrust bulletin
astriking position, and Easterbrook acknowledges that it conflicts
with decisions in other circuits.
While Easterbrook's views are unusual within the judiciary,
they are not so rare among antitrust scholars. For example, Harold
Demsetz3takes a similar position. In contrast, we argue that intent
is a critical factor in distinguishing between competitive and
predatory conduct. What firms intend by their actions is an essen-
tial element in the antitrust concept of predation.
II.
The
economics
of
predatory
conduct
In oligopolistic markets where only a few sellers compete,
firms necessarily behave
strategically.'
That is, they take into
account the reactions of their rivals before deciding on their own
actions. Sometimes, these indirect effects, working through the
reaction of their rivals, are more important than the direct effects
of their actions. Such conduct is designed primarily to affect the
behavior of a rival.
It
could hardly be otherwise in markets with
small numbers of firms.!
Predatory conduct is a particular type of strategic behavior.
Essentially, it requires an investment decision by the predator in
that actions are undertaken, at some current cost to itself, that are
designed specifically to influence arival's behavior in the future.
In the extreme, the rival is induced to leave the market. The
predator expects to earn higher profits in the future with a less
vigorous rival or, better still, with none at all. With less competi-
tion,
higher
prices
can
then be
set
and the
prior
investment
recouped.
3Demsetz, Barriers to Entry, 72 AM.
ECON.
REv. 45 (March 1982).
4Comanor &Frech III, Strategic Behavior and Antitrust Analysis,
74
AM.
ECON.
REv.
372
(May 1984).
SToday, the analysis is usually put in game theoretic terms, but the
ideas predate modern game theory. See Fisher, Games Economists Play:
ANon-cooperative View, 20
RAND
J.
ECON.
113 (Spring
1989);
and
W.
FELLNER,
COMPETITION
AMONG
THE
FEW:
OLIGOPOLY
AND
SIMILAR
MARKET
STRUCTIJRES (1965).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT