Power versus Ideology: Political Group Switching in the European Parliament

Published date01 November 2018
AuthorSimon Hix,Abdul Noury
Date01 November 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/lsq.12202
SIMON HIX
London School of Economics and Political Science
ABDUL NOURY
New York University, Abu Dhabi
Power versus Ideology: Political
Group Switching in the European
Parliament
Why do legislators switch party? We seek to identify whether “party switching”
is mainly determined by power (to join a more influential party) or ideology (to join a
party with closer policy goals). We focus on the 557 cases of political group switching
in the European Parliament between 1979 and 2014. We find that most of these cases
were from smaller, more marginal, and oppositional groups, to larger, more pivotal, and
governing groups. Nevertheless, we also find that ideological congruence (between an
MEP and his or her prospective group) was an important determinant of political group
switching.
Do politicians ultimately seek power, or are they primarily driven
by their ideological convictions? This is an age-old debate in political
science. On one side are scholars like William Riker, who assume that
politicians’ actions are ultimately driven by their desire to maximize their
inf‌luence over political outcomes (e.g., Riker 1962). On the other side
are scholars like Keith Poole, who believe that politicians “die in their
ideological boots” (Poole 2007; Poole and Rosenthal 1997, 100). In this
article, we seek to shed some light on this debate by focusing on the
determinants of why elected politicians switch between political parties.
Do politicians change parties to gain more power or to join their ideolog-
ically similar colleagues?
Most cases of politicians switching between political parties have
happened in the legislative arena rather than in the electoral arena (cf. La
Palombara and Weiner 1966). One interesting case of such “party
switching” is by the Members of the European Parliament (MEPs). The
European Parliament is now a powerful legislative chamber in European
Union (EU) decision making; more akin to the US Congress in the US
“separated-powers” system of government than legislatures in “fused-
powers” parliamentary systems at the national level in Europe and
LEGISLATIVE STUDIES QUARTERLY, 43, 4, No vember 2018
DOI: 10.1111/lsq.12202
V
C2018 Washington University in St. Louis
551
elsewhere. As in the US Congress, legislative majorities in the European
Parliament have to be built issue by issue because neither the EU Com-
mission nor the EU governments command an in-built majority in the
chamber to push bills through. This gives the “political groups” in the
European Parliament signif‌icant legislative power, broadly in proportion
to their size in chamber.
The European Parliament is a good case for focusing in on party
switching because legislative bargaining inside the parliament is largely
isolated from electoral incentives. In most countries in the EU, European
Parliament elections are “national second-order contests”—fought on
the performance of national politicians and parties rather than on the per-
formance of the MEPs or the political groups inside the European
Parliament (Hix and Marsh 2007; Reif and Schmitt 1980).
1
As a result,
internal policy (ideological) and career (power) incentives inside the
European Parliament are stronger drivers of political group switching
than external electoral incentives. This enables us to isolate internal
power and ideological factors in MEPs’ political group switching deci-
sions, which is often not the case in studies of party switching in other
democratic parliaments.
2
Switching political groups inside the European Parliament also has
relatively low transaction costs compared to some other legislatures. In
addition to the low likelihood of domestic electoral punishment for
switching parties inside the chamber, power inside the political groups
(such as committee assignments or leadership positions) is allocated
broadly in proportion to the size of each national “party delegation” in a
group (Benedetto 2007). This means that MEPs can reasonably and
accurately calculate the likely costs and benef‌its of switching when con-
sidering whether to stay in a particular political group or switch to
another one.
Out of 5,179 individual MEPs in the seven elected sessions of the
European Parliament between 1979 and 2014, 504 switched political
group at least once (almost 10%). At face value, this might seem like a
high proportion of the members of a democratic parliament in a 35-year
period. In most established democracies, unlike new democracies,
switching between political parties is a rare occurrence. Yet, given the
lack of potential electoral punishment of switching, the low transaction
costs of joining another group, and the potentially high policy or career
incentives to change groups, the fact that almost 90% of MEPs remained
in the same political group for the duration of their careers in the Euro-
pean Parliament suggests that the political groups in the European
Parliament do represent a certain equilibrium of the individual-level and
collective incentives of the MEPs.
2 Simon Hix and Abdul Noury
378550
552
The rest of the article is organized as follows. We f‌irst discuss the
existing literature on party switching in legislatures before setting out
our own theoretical understanding of why some members in the Euro-
pean Parliament would want to switch political group. In short, we see
each European Parliament election every f‌ive years as an exogenous
shock to the party system equilibrium inside the chamber: adding new
MEPs and new national party delegations and usually new EU member
states too; changing the balance of power between the existing political
groups; and changing the balance of power between the national parties
within the political groups. Individual MEPs and national parties then
consider their policy goals and strategic career incentives and decide
whether to stay or switch political groups, until a new equilibrium
emerges. A key reason why some MEPs want to switch is related to
learning. MEPs learn over time whether their incentives are compatible
with their existing political groups or whether they would be better off
joining a new political group. However, MEPs are likely to think care-
fully before giving up the policy and off‌ice benef‌its they derive from
their existing political group.
We test these ideas in a statistical model of political group switch-
ing for the entire history of the European Parliament. This will allow us
to look at time-series dimension of the data and explore how switching
has evolved as the European Parliament has grown in size and become
more powerful. We use roll-call voting data to measure actual diver-
gence between individual MEPs and their groups’ positions in votes.
Using a pooled logit model, we f‌irst compare switchers to nonswitchers
and show that power and ideology are important determinants of switch-
ing. Our conditional logit model then indicates that both power and
ideology are also important determinants of political “migration” in the
European Parliament. The “power difference” between two prospective
political groups an MEP could belong to has a positive effect on the
probability of switching, meaning that MEPs move to more powerful
political groups. MEPs are also likely to switch to ideologically closer
political groups. Our results also indicate that loyalty, a measure of how
often prior to switching a member votes with his or her party l eader,
decreases the probability of switching, indicating that loyal members are
less likely to switch group.
General Literature on Legislative Party Switching
In a comprehensive review of existing research on legislative party
switching, Carol Mershon points out that a common feature of most
research is that “politicians switch in search of both off‌ice and policy
3Power versus Ideology 379379551553

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT