Portfolio returns and consumption growth covariation in the frequency domain, real economic activity, and expected returns
Published date | 01 September 2022 |
Author | Louis R. Piccotti |
Date | 01 September 2022 |
DOI | http://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12282 |
Received: 12 August 2020
|
Accepted: 15 February 2022
DOI: 10.1111/jfir.12282
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Portfolio returns and consumption growth
covariation in the frequency domain, real
economic activity, and expected returns
Louis R. Piccotti
Department of Finance, Spears School of
Business, Oklahoma State University,
Stillwater, Oklahoma, USA
Correspondence
Louis R. Piccotti, Department of Finance,
Spears School of Business, Oklahoma State
University, Stillwater, OK 74078, USA.
Email: louis.r.piccotti@okstate.edu
Abstract
The slope of the portfolio return and consumption growth
cospectrum contains predictive information about future
real economic activity, future recession probabilities, the
risk aversion coefficient, and future expected returns.
Commonly used economic variables do not subsume the
predictive power of the cospectrum slope and although the
interest rate term spread largely fails to predict the financial
crisis, the set of cospectrum slopes predicts the crisis
with a 75% probability. The cospectrum slope significantly
improves the fit of long‐horizon expected return models
and contains more significant predictive information than
the current dividend yield.
JEL CLASSIFICATION
E44, G01
1|INTRODUCTION
In the frequency domain, the expected return on a portfolio can be viewed as the expected return on a portfolio of
basis assets,
1
which are exposed to consumption risks of various arrival frequencies (Dew‐Becker & Giglio, 2016).
This frequency domain decomposition of the pricing kernel is expressed as a curve, analogous to the term structure
of interest rates. Neuhierl and Varneskov (2021) show that low‐frequency factor loadings using the Fourier
J Financ Res. 2022;45:513–549. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/JFIR
|
513
© 2022 The Southern Finance Association and the Southwestern Finance Association.
1
These basis assets can be viewed heuristically, similar to Arrow–Debreu securities, except that rather than having a payoff of 1 unit in a certain state and
0 in all others, these basis assets have some payoff if a shock arrives with a certain frequency and a 0 payoff for all other shocks arriving at different
frequencies.
transform fit expected portfolio returns better than market betas do. Bandi et al. (2021) form spectral (frequency
exposure) betas using the extended Wold decomposition methodology of Ortu et al. (2020) and show how different
factor portfolios load differently across frequencies and provide evidence that a spectral factor model prices
anomaly portfolios reasonably well.
2
I contribute to the literature on asset pricing in the frequency domain by
examining the information content that the cospectrum (the frequency domain decomposition of the unconditional
covariance) between portfolio returns and consumption growth has for future real economic activity.
The advantage of looking at the frequency domain, rather than the time domain, is that cyclic behavior is more
visible in the frequency domain. As a result, the slope of the cospectrum between portfolio returns and
consumption growth shows how susceptible portfolio returns are to low‐frequency consumption shocks, relative to
high‐frequency consumption shocks. Such a relation would be more difficult to identify in the time domain (e.g.,
with a vector autoregression [VAR] model). This information is valuable, as it is an indicator of investors' abilities to
weather short‐term shocks, such as recessionary periods. For example, van Binsbergen et al. (2013) show that high‐
frequency risks are priced in the market more heavily in recessionary periods. I extend the evidence across this
dimension by additionally showing that the slopes of the cospectra between small‐minus‐big (SMB), high‐minus‐low
(HML), and dividend‐sorted (DIV) portfolio returns and consumption growth are also leading indicators of
recessionary periods, where the SMB and HML cospectra slopes contain the most valuable information for
predicting future recessions.
First, I examine the frequency decomposition in the cross‐section of 25 size and book‐to‐market (BM)
portfolios and find that the cospectra for consumption growth with the market portfolio and the SMB portfolio are
downward sloping, with a greater portion of the risk premium due to low‐frequency risks than to high‐frequency
risks. The higher price for low‐frequency risks is consistent with the long‐run risk models of Bansal and Yaron
(2004) and Bansal et al. (2009). This pattern also indicates that investors in small stocks have a relative implied
preference to smooth their future (higher) consumption versus their present consumption (they display Epstein &
Zin, 1989; preferences). Conversely, the HML and DIV cospectra are upward sloping from low‐frequency risks to
high‐frequency risks. It appears that near‐term risks associated with dividend obligations and the default boundary
are more important to the investors in these portfolios, which suggests that the marginal investors in these stocks
are relatively more concerned with smoothing their near‐term consumption versus their long‐run consumption
(they display internal habit preferences; Abel, 1990; Constantinides, 1990). Although these results suggest a sort of
equities market segmentation, evidence of segmentation in preferences in equities is provided by Dorn and
Huberman (2010), Lease et al. (1976), Menzly and Ozbas (2010), and Wood and Zaichkowsky (2004), among others.
Second, I examine how the slope of the cospectra of portfolio returns and consumption growth changes over
time and how it is related to real economic activity in the United States. This test reveals how investor preferences
for consumption change over time and how these preference shifts are related to future economic growth. The
cospectra using the excess market (EMRKT) and SMB portfolios are generally downward sloping from low‐to high‐
frequency cycles, which suggests Epstein and Zin (1989) preferences (Dew‐Becker & Giglio, 2016); however,
leading up to recessionary periods, the cospectra become more upward sloping from low‐to high‐frequency cycles.
This indicates that leading up to recessionary periods, investors become increasingly concerned with near‐term
consumption needs as would be the case with internal habit preferences (Constantinides, 1990; Dew‐Becker &
Giglio, 2016). Conversely, the portfolio return and consumption growth cospectrum for the HML and DIV portfolios
is evenly split between upward and downward sloping, each approximately equal over time. However, the
cospectra for these portfolios also display sharp shifts toward being upward sloping from low‐to high‐frequency
cycles leading up to recessionary periods. These results are consistent with those found in van Binsbergen et al.
(2013), which show that high‐frequency risks are priced in the market portfolio more heavily surrounding
recessionary periods by examining the time series of dividend strips with varying maturities.
2
In particular, the small Fama–French portfolios load more heavily on risks with cycle periods of 4–8 months, and the high book‐to‐market Fama–French
portfolios load more heavily on risks with cycle periods of 32–64 months.
514
|
JOURNAL OF FINANCIAL RESEARCH
Third, because investors' implied preferences toward smoothing consumption change over time, which is
revealed by the time series of the slope of the portfolio return and consumption growth cospectrum, I examine the
predictive relation between the current cospectrum slope and future real economic growth and recession
probabilities. This complements the literature, which has focused on examining how risks of various frequencies
affect the stochastic discount factor. I find that the slope of the cospectrum is a significant predictor after
controlling for the growth rates of a commonly used set of economic variables. In many cases, the cospectrum slope
is a more significant predictor than the interest rate term spread, which has been shown to have substantial
predictive ability for growth rates in the real economy as well as for recession probabilities (Estrella & Hardouvelis,
1991; Harvey, 1988; Laurent, 1988). Whereas the term spread provides information about future consumption
demands (primarily through the inflation premium), the shape of the portfolio return and consumption growth
cospectrum provides information about investors' timing preferences for consumption. That is, the cospectrum
slope indicates whether investors need to shift future consumption to the present (e.g., to meet liquidity needs) or
whether their current consumption is durable and they have the capacity to shift consumption from the present to
the future to attain a higher level of consumption from investing.
The portfolio return and consumption growth cospectrum slope alone is a good predictor (using a probit model)
of 12‐month forward recession probabilities (a pseudo R
2
of 0.41), and the information contained in the cospectrum
slope is not simply a manifestation of the information in the interest rate term spread. The most compelling case for
this is that the term spread generates a 30% recession probability for a financial crisis, whereas the set of
cospectrum slopes generates a 75% recession probability. When the recession probability probit model includes
both the interest rate term spread and the set of cospectrum slopes, the model estimates 12‐month forward
recession probabilities very well. The full probit recession model probability model attains a pseudo R
2
of 0.658
versus a pseudo R
2
of 0.523 attained from the univariate interest rate term spread model and predicts the financial
crisis with a recession probability in excess of 80%.
Finally, I examine the relation between the portfolio return and consumption growth cospectrum slope and
expected returns. Long‐horizon expected return regressions show that the slope significantly predicts future excess
market returns, with the slope more significantly related to future expected returns than the current dividend yield
is (the second most significant predictor). Therefore, the cospectrum slope contains valuable information for
investors as well, which is further evidenced by the utility gains attained by using a trading strategy, which
conditions on the slope of the cospectrum.
2|LITERATURE REVIEW
This article fits into the literature on the term structure of the risk premium. van Binsbergen et al. (2012) and van
Binsbergen et al. (2013) examine the equity risk premium by looking at the pricing of dividend strips with various
maturities and find that the term structure is generally upward sloping in maturity. They attribute the shape and
time‐varying behavior of the equity term structure to dividend growth rates and risk premia. van Binsbergen and
Koijen (2016) further attempt to reconcile the shape of the term structure of equity with common asset pricing
models. They conclude that the pattern in dividend strip prices is not consistent with the Lucas (1978) consumption
capital asset pricing model (CAPM), external habit preferences (Abel, 1990; Campbell & Cochrane, 1999), long‐run
consumption risks (Bansal & Yaron, 2004), or by variable rare disasters (Gabaix, 2012). Otrok et al. (2002) cast doubt
on the ability of internal habit preference models (Constantinides, 1990) to explain the risk premium. In contrast to
these studies, Lettau and Wachter (2007,2011) show that the risk premium should be downward sloping with long‐
horizon equity (growth stocks) having lower expected returns than short‐horizon equity (value stocks). Croce et al.
(2015) further show that the term structure of equity can be downward sloping with bounded rationality, but is
upward sloping with full information. The differing shapes of the term structure of the risk premium can be
reconciled, however, when firms have dividend policies that lead to stationary leverage (Belo et al., 2015).
PORTFOLIO RETURNS AND CONSUMPTION GROWTH COVARIATION
|
515
Get this document and AI-powered insights with a free trial of vLex and Vincent AI
Get Started for FreeStart Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting
