“Portfolio Effects” in Merger Analysis: Differences between EU and U.S. Practice and Recommendations for the Future

DOI10.1177/0003603X0404900103
AuthorEric R. Emch
Published date01 March 2004
Date01 March 2004
Subject MatterAntitrust in the U.S. and the EU: Converging or Diverging Paths?
The Antitrust Bulletin/Spring-Summer 2004
"PortfoIio effects" in merger
analysis: differences between
EU
and U.S. practice and
recommendations for the future
BY ERIC R. EMCH*
I.
Despite
convergence,
significant
differences
remain
55
The past decade has seen an enhanced vigor of antitrust enforcement
within the European Union (EU), and an increasing convergence
between its enforcement practices and those of the United States.
Recent enforcement decisions by the respective agencies for the most
part have reflected a consensus among enforcers on both sides of the
Atlantic on the proper goals of antitrust and the appropriate analytical
methods.' At the same time, however, perhaps thrown into relief by
*Economist, U.S. Department of Justice, Washington, DC.
AUTHOR'S NOTE: I thank the University
of
Chicago Law School
for
sup-
port during the writing
of
this article via the Victor Kramer Foundation
Fellowship. Ialso thank Norman Familant, Kenneth Heyer,
Robert
Majure, Russell Pittman, and Gisle Torheim
for
helpful conversations
and comments on various aspects
of
this article during its evolution, and
the editors, Gunnar Niels and Adriaan ten Kate, for numerous valuable
suggestions
for
the final version. The views expressed in this article are
not purported to represent those
of
the U.S. Department
of
Justice, nor
those
of
any
of
the individuals thanked above.
See Antitrust in the U.S. and Europe: A History of Convergence,
Speech by European Commissioner Mario Monti Before the General
©2004 by Federal Legal Publications. Inc.
56 The antitrust bulletin
agreement
on the
broad
contours
of
antitrust policy, astrain
of
argument in merger decisions by the European Commission has
emerged that signals important differences in philosophy between it
and the enforcement agencies
of
the United States.
The set
of
concerns articulated by the Commission, sometimes
labeled as "portfolio," "range," or "conglomerate" effects but not
always assigned aparticular label.? generally lies outside of current
merger enforcement practice in the United States. Indeed, while there
is some debate over what "portfolio effects" actually means and when
a merger is or is not a "portfolio effects" case, for the purpose of this
article the term will refer to broad concerns raised by the Commission
in nonhorizontal, nonvertical mergers that usually appear as a group
and are for the most part outside U.S. merger enforcement practice.
The
purpose
of
this
article
is to
identify
more
clearly
the
differences between the jurisdictions in their treatment of portfolio
effects and to outline a path toward greater convergence. It examines
in detail European Commission, U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ),
and Federal Trade Commission (FTC) enforcement decisions in cases
that have raised portfolio effects or similar concerns, and also studies
the economics
of
an important subset of portfolio effects
concerns-
anticompetitive
tying-with
an eye toward reconciling U.S. and EU
positions with the lessons
of
economic theory.
The fundamental concern raised in portfolio effects cases is that a
merger
of
firms without a direct horizontal or vertical relationship (or
aspects
of
a merger that do not involve direct horizontal or vertical
connections)
will
harm
consumer
welfare
by
enhancing
the
Counsel Roundtable
of
the American Bar Association, Nov. 14, 2001
(text available at European Commission Web site europa.eu.int), Interna-
tional
Antitrust
in the 21 st Century: Cooperation
and
Convergence,
Speech
by
the
then-U.S.
Assistant
Attorney General Charles James
Before the OECD Global Forum on Competition, Oct. 17, 2001 (text
available at U.S. DOJ Web site www.usdoj.gov/atr).
2
For
instance, the October 2001 Commission decision in Tetra-
Laval/Sidel (Case No. COMPIM.2416) outlines many concerns that in the
past
have been labeled portfolio/range/conglomerate effects, without
labeling them as such.
Portfolio effects :57
"dominance toolkit" of the merging firm, which now produces a wider
range of goods than had been produced by either firm premerger,' The
enhanced power that the merging firm derives from producing an
expanded
range
of
goods is in some
circumstances
seen as so
debilitating to the prospects of the firm's rivals that the competitive
constraint offered by rival firms will be
reduced-either
they will be
forced to exit the marketaltogether or they will reduce ongoing R&D
or other spending required to remain effective competitors. This
reduction in competition drives the ultimate harm to consumers.
The European Commission has focused on various mechanisms
behind these effects, often within the same merger. A common story is
that the merger will give the new firm an increased scope for tying
products in a way that will force competitor exit or pullback. Another
is that the merger will allow the firm to offer a low-priced bundle of
goods that competitors cannot replicate. Another that cost reductions
from economies of scale or scope on the demand or supply side will
give
the
merged
firm
a
large
and
lasting
advantage
over
its
competitors. Finally, some cases add to this mix a general fear that a
larger firm will be more powerful due to its size, through an increase
in its access to capital or bargaining power,for example. This is seen,
for instance, to enable predatory strategies that were previously
unavailable to the independent firms.
Each mechanism of harm that has been raised in portfolio effects
cases has a different implication for consumers. A tie supported by
monopoly power that would stifle competition in an emerging market,
for example, has a quite different impact on consumer welfare than
supply-side scale or
scope
economies
or
"one-stop
shopping"
The phrase "dominance toolkit" is taken from the GElHoneywell
decision,
footnote
101
(Case
No.
COMP/M.2220).
Though
some
European Commission officials have argued that the GElHoneywell case
was
not
technically
a
"portfolio
effects"
case
(see
Unbundling
GE/Honeywel1: The Assessment of Conglomerate Mergers Under EC
Competition Law, Address by Gotz Drauz Before the Fordham Corporate
Law Institute's 28th Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law
and Policy, Oct. 2001), it fits the pattern of many past portfolio effects
cases, and falls within the definition of a portfolio effects case used in
this article.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT