Portfolio Choice in Retirement—What is The Optimal Home Equity Release Product?

AuthorMichael Sherris,Katja Hanewald,Thomas Post
Date01 June 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12068
Published date01 June 2016
PORTFOLIO CHOICE IN RETIREMENTWHAT IS THE
OPTIMAL HOME EQUITY RELEASE PRODUCT?
Katja Hanewald
Thomas Post
Michael Sherris
ABSTRACT
We study the decision problem of the optimal choice between home equity
release products from a retired homeowner’s perspective in the presence of
longevity, long-term care, house price, and interest rate risk. The individual
can choose to release home equity using reverse mortgages or home
reversion plans, to buy annuities, and long-term care insurance. The
individual enjoys utility gains from having access to either one of the two
equity release products. Higher utility gains are found for the reverse
mortgage, as its product features allow for higher lump-sum payouts and
provide downside protection for house prices.
INTRODUCTION
We study the decision problem of the optimal choice between different home equity
release products from the perspective of a retired homeowner in the presence of
longevity, long-term care, house price, and interest rate risk. For elderly homeowners,
Katja Hanewald is at the Australian Research Council Centre of Excellence in Population
Ageing Research (CEPAR), Australian School of Business, University of New South Wales,
Sydney, Australia. Hanewald can be contacted via e-mail: hanewaldk@gmail.com. Thomas
Post is at the Department of Finance, School of Business and Economics, Maastricht University
and Netspar. Post can be contacted via e-mail: t.post@maastrichtuniversity.nl. Michael Sherris
is at the School of Risk and Actuarial Studies and Australian Research Council Centre of
Excellence in Population Ageing Research (CEPAR), Australian School of Business, University
of New South Wales, Sydney, Australia. Sherris can be contacted via e-mail: m.sherris@unsw.
edu.au. The authors acknowledge the support of ARC Linkage Grant Project LP0883398
“Managing Risk with Insurance and Superannuation as Individuals Age” with industry
partners PwC and APRA and the Australian Research Council Centre of Excellence in
Population Ageing Research (Project number CE110001029). We thank the editor, Keith
Crocker, and two anonymous reviewers for their suggestions to improve the paper. For their
comments and suggestions we would like to thank Kevin Ahlgrim, Hua Chen, and the
conference participants at the 20th Annual Colloquium of Superannuation Researchers and
the 2012 Annual Meeting of the American Risk and Insurance Association. Rachel Nakhle and
Yu Sun provided excellent research assistance.
© 2015 The Journal of Risk and Insurance. Vol. 83, No. 2, 421–446 (2016).
DOI: 10.1111/jori.12068
421
the home’s equity is often the most significant asset. For example, the value of the
primary residence for U.S. households aged 65þcomprises on average (median) 49
percent (52 percent) of total assets, with 82 percent of households owning a house
(2009 Survey of Consumer Finance). To use the home’s equity for consumption
purposes generally would require selling the home and renting a place instead
(a decision problem covered, for example, in Yao and Zhang, 2005). However, many
homeowners are reluctant to sell the home. They prefer to “age in place” (Davidoff,
2010c). For these homeowners, home equity release products allow elderly
homeowners to convert the equity in their home into liquid wealth without having
to move. Home equity release contracts differ substantially in the way house price
risks, interest rate risk, and longevity risk are shared between the homeowner and
the provider of the product. To make the right product choice is an important
question for an elderly homeowner—we address this normative research question in
this article.
Markets for equity release products for retirees exist in numerous countries including
the United States, the United Kingdom, Australia, Canada, New Zealand, and several
countries in the European Union. The two main forms of equity release are reverse
mortgage schemes (“loan model”) and home reversion schemes (“sale model”) (see,
e.g., Hosty et al., 2008; Reifner et al., 2009a). Reflecting those market conditions, we
model a retiree’s choice between a reverse mortgage and a home reversion plan.
Reverse mortgages are the mo st common products interna tionally and dominate
the U.S. market (Consumer Finan cial Protection Bureau, 2012) . When taking out a
reverse mortgage, the home owner receives a lump-sum pa yment (or annuity or
line of credit) through borrow ing against the home’s value. There are no regular
interest payments on the mortgag e; instead, interest is added (rolle d up) to the
loan balance over time. The loan is paid back when the homeowner mo ves out
or dies. Even if the loan balanc e becomes larger than the home ’s value, the
homeowner has the right to cont inue residing in the home and the loan amount that
has to be paid back is typicall y capped by the home’s value (no n egative equity
guarantee [NNEG]).
Home reversion has existed for a long time in the form of private arrangements, for
example, in France, Portugal, and Poland (Reifner et al., 2009b). Commercial home
reversion is available, for example, in Australia, France, Finland, New Zealand, and
the United Kingdom. With a home reversion plan, the homeowner sells (a part of) his
home in exchange for a lump sum. The homeowner keeps the right to live in the home
as long as he lives. When the homeowner moves out or dies there is no payment to the
provider of the home reversion plan. However, as compensation for the life-long right
to live in the home, the provider of the plan reduces the upfront lump-sum payment
by the present value of future rent payments.
Alai et al. (2014) compare the cash flows and risk profile of stylized reverse mortgage
and home reversion plans from the perspective of the product provider. The
comparison shows that for loan-to-value ratios (LTVs) of less than 50 percent reverse
mortgages are more profitable and less risky for the provider than home reversion
plans. The opposite is true for higher LTVs (which are rare outside of the U.S. market).
This finding may explain why more reverse mortgages than home reversion
422 THE JOURNAL OF RISK AND INSURANCE

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT