A Political Economy Model of Earnings Mobility and Redistribution Policy

AuthorRYO ARAWATARI,TETSUO ONO
Date01 June 2015
Published date01 June 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12112
APOLITICAL ECONOMY MODEL OF EARNINGS MOBILITY
AND REDISTRIBUTION POLICY
RYO ARAWATARI
Nagoya University
TETSUO ONO
Osaka University
Abstract
This paper presents a politico-economic model that in-
cludes a mutual link between life cycle earnings mobility
and redistributive politics. The model demonstrates that
when an economy features a high opportunity of upward
mobility and high risk of downward mobility, it attains
a unique equilibrium where unskilled, low-income agents
support a low redistribution because of the hope of upward
mobility in future. In contrast, the economy attains multiple
equilibria when mobility opportunity and risk are low: one
is an unskilled-majority equilibrium defined by low mobil-
ity and the other is a skilled-majority equilibrium defined by
high mobility. The paper gives a comparison between the
political equilibrium and the social planner’s allocation in
terms of mobility, and shows that the skilled-majority equi-
librium realizes mobility close to the optimal one.
1. Introduction
Expectations of redistribution affect individuals’ decisions on educational
investment. Their decisions determine the distribution of skilled and
unskilled agents and thus inequality among agents, which in turn has an
Ryo Arawatari, Graduate School of Economics, Nagoya University, Furo-cho, Chikusa-ku,
Nagoya, Aichi 464-8601, Japan (arawatari@soec.nagoya-u.ac.jp). Tetsuo Ono, Graduate
School of Economics, Osaka University, 1-7, Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043,
Japan (tono@econ.osaka-u.ac.jp).
The authors would like to thank associate editor and two anonymous referees for their
valuable comments and suggestions. Financial support of the Nomura Foundation is grate-
fully acknowledged.
Received October 5, 2013; Accepted October 11, 2013.
C2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Public Economic Theory, 17 (3), 2015, pp. 346–382.
346
Earnings Mobility and Redistribution Policy 347
impact upon individuals’ votes over redistribution. This feedback mecha-
nism between individual decisions and redistributive politics could produce
multiple equilibria (Glomm and Ravikumar 1995, Saint-Paul and Verdier
1997, Benabou 2000). Based on the concept of a stationary Markov-perfect
equilibrium, Hassler et al. (2003) and Hassler, Storesletten, and Zilibotti
(2007) capture the feedback mechanism and demonstrate multiple equi-
libria that explain the cross-country variations in welfare programs among
democratic countries sharing similar economic backgrounds.
While the analysis by Hassler et al. (2003, 2007) provided a key insight
into redistributive politics, it leaves the earning mobility issue untouched.
In their framework, agents who succeed in education during their youth
retain their skills over their life cycle without any additional effort, and thus
face no risk of downward mobility such as job loss or demotion. In addition,
agents who fail in education during their youth have no second opportu-
nity of becoming skilled at a later stage of their life and thus must accept
their low-income status throughout their life. In an earlier study (Arawatari
and Ono 2009), we considered a mutual link between upward mobility and
redistributive politics by introducing an upward mobility opportunity into
the framework of Hassler et al. (2007).1However, the downward mobility is
omitted from the analysis, and the normative implication of mobility in the
political equilibrium allocation in the presence of earnings mobility is left
untouched.
While previous studies contribute to our knowledge and understand-
ing of mobility and redistributive politics, the following issues still remain
unresolved: (i) how do redistributive politics interact with mobility and dis-
tribution of income in the presence of both upward mobility chance and
downward mobility risk, and (ii) how does the political equilibrium outcome
depart from the commitment solution (called the Ramsey allocation) with
respect to earnings mobility and redistribution? Answers to these questions
will provide more general insights into mobility and redistributive politics.
For the purpose of analysis, we adopt a framework based on that
developed by Hassler et al. (2007) and that extended by Arawatari and
Ono (2009). We further extend this framework by introducing a downward
mobility risk of agents. In particular, we consider agents living in two periods,
youth and old age. In youth, agents undertake educational investments that
determine whether their status in youth is skilled (i.e., rich) or unskilled (i.e.,
poor). At the beginning of old age, unskilled agents have an opportunity of
upward mobility with a probability γ, and can increase the probability of
becoming skilled via reinvestment in education. By contrast, skilled agents
are at risk of downward mobility with a probability γ×θ, but they can reduce
1Early work by Piketty (1995) and Quadrini (1999) considered the effect of earnings mo-
bility on agents’ preferences for redistribution. However, a mutual link between mobility
and redistributive politics is omitted from their analysis because of the assumption of ex-
ogenous mobility or idiosyncratic shocks to mobility.
348 Journal of Public Economic Theory
the probability of becoming poor by reinvestment in education. The expec-
tations of redistribution affect the agents’ decisions on education, which in
turn determines voting behavior over redistribution policy and thus mobility
in the economy.
Focusing on the two key parameters, γand θ, we first present the
political equilibrium allocation via majority voting and investigate how the
two parameters affect the political equilibrium outcome. When the upward
mobility opportunity is high such that γis above the threshold value, the
economy attains a unique, unskilled-majority equilibrium with no taxation
on the old, representing the United States. A high prospect of upward mo-
bility (POUM) in the future gives agents a disincentive to invest in education
in youth, but they support no taxation on the old because of the POUM in
the future (Benabou and Ok 2001, Alesina and La Ferrara 2005).
In contrast, when γis below the threshold value, the economy attains
multiple equilibria, representing some European countries. One equilib-
rium is an unskilled-majority equilibrium with taxation on the old, represent-
ing those Continental European countries that feature high inequality and
low mobility; and the other is a skilled-majority equilibrium with no taxation
on the old, representing Scandinavian countries defined by low inequality
and high mobility. Which equilibrium is realized as an outcome depends on
the expectations of the agents.
The parameter θ, representing the risk of downward mobility, also af-
fects agents’ decisions on education. In particular, a higher θgives agents a
disincentive to invest in education during youth because, for skilled agents,
one’s status in youth is less likely to persist into old age. Given this feature, a
natural prediction is that in an economy with a high prospect of downward
mobility the majority will be unskilled agents who support taxation on the
skilled old. However, this prediction is not true. A higher θimplies a lower
number of the skilled old and thus less redistributive benefit from taxation
on the skilled old. The redistributive benefit is outweighed by the expected
tax burden of the unskilled who may become the skilled via reinvestment
in education. Therefore, a higher downward mobility risk is more likely to
realize an equilibrium supporting the POUM hypothesis. Upward mobility
opportunity and downward mobility risk produce qualitatively similar prop-
erties with respect to political equilibrium characterization: this result was
not shown in Hassler et al. (2007) and Arawatari and Ono (2009).
Another noteworthy feature of the political equilibrium is that the rela-
tive number of upwardly and downwardly mobile agents are completely dif-
ferent between the two types of unskilled-majority equilibrium. The number
of upwardly mobile agents is larger than the number of downwardly mobile
agents in the unskilled-majority equilibrium with no taxation on the old,
representing the United States. However, the opposite result holds in the
unskilled-majority equilibrium with taxation on the old, representing some
Continental European countries. Whether the old are taxed or not criti-
cally affects the relative number of upwardly and downwardly mobile agents.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT