Political Consequences of Conglomerate Mergers

AuthorThomas G. Marx
DOI10.1177/0003603X8202700104
Published date01 March 1982
Date01 March 1982
Subject MatterArticle
The Antitrust Bulletin/Spring 1982 107
Political consequences
of
conglomerate
mergers
BY THOMAS G.
MARX·
I.
Introduction
The debate over legislation to prohibit conglomerate mergers is
heating up again as a result of accelerated merger activity in the
first half of
1981
and the huge du Pont-Conoco deal. Conglomer-
ate mergers first increased in relative importance following the
passage of the Celler-Kefauver Act in 1950, which substantially
extended the reach
of
section 7 of the Clayton Act to horizontal
and vertical mergers. Conglomerate merger activity peaked in
1968, but then began to increase again in the mid-1970s. This
renewed activity led to proposed legislation in the 96th Congress
to restrict conglomerate mergers among large firms. Senator
Kennedy sponsored a bill that would prohibit all mergers between
companies with more than $2 billion in sales or assets, and
require companies with sales or assets over $350 million to
demonstrate that the merger would enhance competition or in-
crease efficiency. IInterest in this legislation waned, however, with
Director, Economic Policy Studies, General Motors Corp.
AUTHOR'S NOTE: The assistance
of
T. Walton and E. Eckard is grate-
fully acknowledged; however, all opinions and any errors are solely the
responsibility (}f the author.
IThe Small and Independent Business Protection Act
of
1979, S.
600, 96th Cong., 1st Sess., S2417-19 (1979).
©1982by Federal LegalPublications. Inc.
108 The antitrust bulletin
the Republican victories in the Senate; Strom Thurmond's re-
placement of Senator Kennedy as head
of
the Judiciary Commit-
tee (and the subsequent abolishment
of
the Subcommittee on
Antitrust and Monopolies); and the development
of
more press-
ing macroeconomic problems.
Recent developments, however, have rekindled the conglomer-
ate merger debate. Mid-year
1981
data indicate that mergers and
acquisitions are running
50010
ahead
of
1980 levels.' During the
first six months of
1981
there were 1,184 transactions with a value
of
$35.7 billion compared with 1980 totals of 1,889 transactions
worth $44.3 billion.3Interest in conglomerate mergers has also
been recently sparked by the
views
of
new antitrust chief William
F. Baxter, who has promised a revision of the 1968 merger
guidelines. Baxter is concerned with the horizontal consequences
of
mergers (e.g., the elimination
of
potential entry) and not with
size per se.
The focus of these debates represents a marked shift from
economic to socio-political arguments against conglomerate
mergers among large firms. The reason for this lies in the demise
of
earlier economic arguments against size per se. Early observa-
tions of profit-concentration relationships have proved largely
transitory or consistent with large-firm efficiency, which looms
ever more important with increasing competition from large,
foreign multinationals. Aggregate concentration, deep-pocket,
reciprocal dealing and mutual forbearance theories have all been
2Mergers and Acquisitions 16, no. 2 (Summer 1981): 4.
3
"Don't
Stop the Mating
Game,"
Fortune 104, no. 4 (24 August
1981): 70. As a result of these merger developments, Rep. John
Seiberling (D-Ohio) introduced a bill similar to S. 600 that would
prohibit mergers between companies with sales or assets exceeding $2
billion, and also prevent mergers between companies with sales or assets
of $350 million unless the companies could prove that the mergers
would increase competition or economic efficiency. The Small and
Independent Business Protection Act
of
1981, H.R. 4409, 97th Cong.,
1st Sess., E 3939-40 (1981).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT