Policy-Based Defenses

AuthorFranklin G. Snyder, Mark Edwin Burge
Pages307-332
______________________________________________________________________________
UNIT 16: POLICY-BASED DEFENSES 307
Unit 16
__________________________________________________________________
CONTRACT DEFENSES
Part Four
__________________________________________________________________
Policy-Based Defenses
FOCUS OF THIS UNIT
Enforceability is what makes a contract different from a mere agreement.
Enforceability means that the parties can enlist the coercive power of the government
to make the breaching party do what it promised to do (in some cases), or pay
damages for failing to do so (in far more cases). As a consequence, the “private”
agreement between the parties has a “public” aspect to it. While the private ordering
agreed to by the parties predominates, the public at large actually has some interest
in those things to which the private parties can and cannot agree. For these reasons
several defenses to otherwise enforceable contracts are what we call “policy-based.”
There is some enforcement that the government simply will not do.
Enforcement is Good, Except When It Isn’t. The common-law system of
contracts rests on a general premise that enforcing private agreements is a good thing
and is therefore an important public policy of the state. Governments have many
other policies, however, and sometimes those policies conflict with the policy that
parties should be free to contract as they see fit.
Illegal Contracts. Very early on, for example, courts would not uphold
contracts that were themselves illegal (such as contracts to fix prices in violation of
antitrust law), or that called for the commission of crimes or torts (such as murder or
property damage), or that violated public morals (such as gambling or prosti tution).
The basic rule with respect to such contracts is that they are void (not merely
voidable). This means that if A has paid B $10,000 to kill C, and B fails to do so, A
cannot bring a contract claim to recover the payment. If a customer fails to pay a
prostitute or a drug dealer for goods or services, or a prostitute or drug dealer fails to
deliver what was promised, no contract remedy generally exists. We will see later
that in some cases courts may order restitution of benefits conferred in some more
technical categories of illegality (which would not include murder, prostitution, or
illegal drugs).
______________________________________________________________________________
308 CHAPTER V: CONTRACT DEFENSES
Against Public Policy. In many situations, a particular contract is not
specifically illegal, but enforcing the deal would require the courtan agency of the
governmentto act contrary to other important government interests.
For purposes of analyzing these “public policy” types of cases, it is useful to
start with a simple framework. First, is there a significant public policy involved?
Such policies may be found in statutes or in the common law, but the initial step is to
figure out exactly what the policy is. Second, would enforcement of the contract
conflict with that policy? What exactly is the interference that is threatened? Third,
do the public policy concerns outweigh the public interest in enforcing contracts
generally? These situations can vary a great deal from one jurisdiction to the next,
making it difficult to make any categorical statements about American law here.
Consider, for instance, the In re Baby M surrogacy contract from the beginning of the
course. What New Jersey found unenforceable might find a welcome home in another
state. Review Chapter 8 (“Unenforceability on Grounds of Public Policy”) of the
Restatement (Second) of Contracts (§§ 178 199) to get a general feel for the current
state of public-policy analysis in contract law.
As you might gather, public policy is often in the mind of the beholder. Courts
(and legislatures, too) can and do strongly disagree amongst themselves over the
existence of particular policies, over whether particular contracts conflict with those
policies, and over how conflicting policies should be weighed against one another.
Three of the most common and important categories of contracts that involve public
policies are (1) contracts that restrict competition, (2) contracts that limit tort
liability, and (3) contracts that impair family law obligations. We already saw the
third category in the Baby M case, so the readings below will address the first two.
Unconscionability: Policing Fairness. Beyond the long-established concept of
contracts against public policy is the much more recent doctrine of unconscionability.
Historically, the common law did not let people out of bad bargains unless they fell
under one of the assent-based defensesfraud, misrepresentation, duress, undue
influence, or mistake. In some contracts, no one has lied, no threat has been made,
no party’s free will has been taken away, and no party has made a fundamental
mistake. Despite the absence of traditional defenses, the deal itself seems so unfair
that courts will refuse to enforce it. These were sometimes said to be contracts that
“no honest man would offer and no sane man would sign.” Despite its noble intentions,
unconscionability doctrine has proven to be a particular challenge in its actual
application.
_____________________

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT