How Personalist Parties Undermine State Capacity in Democracies

Published date01 November 2023
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/00104140231169014
AuthorJia Li,Joseph Wright
Date01 November 2023
Subject MatterArticles
Article
Comparative Political Studies
2023, Vol. 56(13) 20302065
© The Author(s) 2023
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/00104140231169014
journals.sagepub.com/home/cps
How Personalist Parties
Undermine State
Capacity in Democracies
Jia Li
1
and Joseph Wright
2
Abstract
How do political parties shape state capacity? We argue that democratic
leaders backed by personalist parties are more likely than other leaders to
undermine impartial state administration. Personalist parties are those where
the leader has more control over the party than other senior party elites.
Elites in these parties have careers closely tied to the leader, are unlikely to
normatively value an impersonal bureaucracy, and lack collective action
capacity independent from the leader. Therefore, personalist parties are less
likely than other parties to restrain leaders from undermining impartial state
administration. Results from various designs for causal inference show that
party personalism decreases impersonal state administration, particularly
when the party controls a legislative majority. However, party personalism
does not inf‌luence other dimensions of state capacity, such as f‌iscal capacity or
territorial control. The f‌indings have implications for how political parties
enable democratically elected leaders to erode open-access societies and
ultimately, democracy.
Keywords
political parties, democracy, personalism, state capacity, impartial bureaucracy
1
Utah State University, Logan, UT, USA
2
Pennsylvania State University, University Park, PA, USA
Corresponding Author:
Jia Li, Utah State University, Department of Political Science, 0725 Old Main Hill, Logan, UT
84322-0725, USA.
Email: jiali.polisci@gmail.com
Even before the unsuccessful coup attempt in the summer of 2016 in Turkey,
President Erdo ˘
gans party, the Justice and Development Party (AKP), attacked
the Turkish state bureaucracy because it threatened his hold on power. Indeed
the largely secular state had set a precedent, orchestrating the fall of an earlier
government led by an Islamic party in 1997, four years prior to the AKPs
foundingin 2001. Beginning with his own party,Erdo˘
gan consolidatedpersonal
power and thenproceeded to undermine the statebureaucracy (Lancaster,2014,
168283). His attacks on the state included targets such as government min-
istries, internalintelligence agencies, the legislature,the judiciary, and even the
central bank (Demiralp & Demiralp, 2019). In the wake of the 2016 coup
attempt, Erdo˘
gans government dismissed or detained perhaps as many as
100,000 public sector employees (Amnesty International, 2017,4).
A similar storyhas unfolded in Hungary in the past decade.After Fidesz won
parliamentaryelections in 2010, the leaderof the victorious party,Viktor Orb´
an,
began attackingthe institutions of the state. Shortly aftercoming to power, the
Orb´
an administration[introduced] laws that havemade the immediate dismissal
of public employees without cause possible, and so, too, the cleansing of the
entire governmentapparatus. As a result, centraland local public administration
[were] quickly politicized(Bozóki, 2011, 11). Indeed, after the 2010 election,
the top four hierarchical levels of centralgovernment bureaucracy were almost
entirely purged,cementing Orb´
ans power over the state (Hajnal & Boda,
2021, 81). In the process, [Orb´
an] hasmade the public sector less ac-
countableto citizens(Comelli & Horv´
ath, 2018). Andperhaps most pernicious
for impartialstate administration, Orb´
anspartyhas quietly taken controlof the
boards that run many state institutionsto hedge against the possibility that
Fidesz loses its legislative super-majority (Roth, 2021). Orb´
an is creating
foundations run by cronies that will control many state resources and operate
beyond the oversight of the legislature(Roth, 2021).
Erdo˘
gan and Orb´
an were f‌irst elected in free and fair elections under
democratic rule; and both quickly took aim at the state bureaucracy in the
process consolidating their hold on power. However, even prior to politicizing
the state, these leaders took control over the political party that launched their
electoral careers, a process we refer to as personalizing their parties. Con-
sequently, the personalized parties that backed these rulers proved unable to
restrain their subsequent attacks on the state. Indeed, personalist parties were
central to the process of eroding impartial state administration and consoli-
dating the leaders power over the state.
This paper asks how personalized political parties shape impartial state
administrative and bureaucratic capacity in democracies. We argue that
leaders backed by personalist parties undermine and politicize the state bu-
reaucracy in an effort to consolidate power. All political leadersthose
backed by personalist parties and those who lead non-personalized
partieshave an incentive to politically align state bureaucracies with
Li and Wright 2031
their policy priorities, to both help solve delegation problems and reduce
bureaucratic constraints on their power. Politicizing the bureaucracy reduces
state capacity, conceptualized as an impartial and impersonal administrative
bureaucracy.
Parties where elites have better career prospects independent of the current
leader restrain incumbents from politicizing the state because their careers
depend more on the established, non-personalist party and its reputation,
rather than on the current leader. Thus, they are more likely to pay future
policy and electoral costs for politicizing the bureaucracy well after the current
leader leaves off‌ice. In contrast, when leaders are backed by personalist
parties, rulers select loyal elites with career fates tied to the leader, which
aligns personalist party elitesinterests with their leaders political career. And
even if elites in personalist parties want to stop the leaders politicization of the
state bureaucracy, they may not have the collective action capacity to prevent
the leader from doing so. Together, the leadersincentive to undermine
impartial state administration and party eliteslack of incentive or inability to
stop this process mean that leaders backed by personalist parties should be
more likely to politicize state bureaucracies than leaders who are not backed
by personalist parties.
However, all leaders, even those backed by personalist parties, still require
revenue from the economy to sustain their rule and prefer control over the
states territory. They thus do not necessarily have an incentive to harm state
f‌iscal capacity or the territorial reach and power of the state. Since Fidesz took
power in 2010, Hungary saw no signif‌icant reduction in its public revenue
relative to the size of its economy (World Bank, 2022). While Orb´
an used pre-
election f‌iscal handouts to boost its popular support (Szakacs, 2022), his
government looked for new revenues from tax increase on small businesses to
new windfall taxes on big ones (Dunai, 2022;France-Presse, 2022). In
Turkey,Erdo ˘
gans government asserted territorial control over its borders with
growing repression against its Kurdish population (Butler, 2021) as well as
military attacks on Kurds in Syria and Iraq (Burc, 2019;Jongerden, 2019).
These cases suggest that personalist parties may undermine impersonal ad-
ministrative and bureaucratic capacity without necessarily hindering other
components of state capacity.
State bureaucraticcapacity has been linked to better development outcomes
(e.g., Evans & Rauch, 1999) and long-term economic growth and investment
(e.g., Besley & Persson, 2010;Knack & Keefer, 1995;Knutsen, 2013)aswell
as public service delivery essential for boosting health and education and re-
ducing poverty (e.g., Cingolani et al., 2015;Hanson, 2015;Henderson et al.,
2007). Others note that bureaucratic quality enables developmental statesto
enact coherent growth-oriented policies (e.g., Johnson, 1982) and provides
states with more policy options for dealing with macro-economic volatility
(e.g., Franco Chuaire et al., 2017;Haggard & Kaufman, 1992). Further, state
2032 Comparative Political Studies 56(13)

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT