Personal Networks, State Financial Backing, and Foreign Direct Investment

Published date01 June 2023
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/00104140221139382
AuthorSeungjun Kim
Date01 June 2023
Subject MatterArticles
Article
Comparative Political Studies
2023, Vol. 56(7) 10001028
© The Author(s) 2022
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/00104140221139382
journals.sagepub.com/home/cps
Personal Networks, State
Financial Backing, and
Foreign Direct
Investment
Seungjun Kim
Abstract
The new, new trade theoryargues that f‌irm-specif‌ic attributes such as size
explain why large f‌irms predominantly engage in foreign direct investment
(FDI) and thus reap most of the rewards of globalization. However, studies
have neglected the importance of f‌irmspolitical inf‌luence over core f‌inancial
institutions. I argue that large f‌irms engage in greater FDI in part because of
their political connections, which allow them to receive government loans in
support of FDI. Using a unique, hand-coded dataset that includes 4936
directors of South Korean f‌irms and these f‌irmsFDI announcements, I show
that f‌irms that place elite f‌inancial off‌icials on their boards engage in greater
FDI than f‌irms without such board-member connections. Therefore, the
outsized gains that large f‌irms receive from globalization are dependent on
their political ties to their home government.
Keywords
foreign direct investment, political connections, state f‌inancing
University of California Merced, Merced, CA, USA
Corresponding Author:
Seungjun Kim, University of California Merced, 5200 North Lake Rd, Merced, CA 95343-5001,
USA.
Email: skim408@ucmerced.edu
Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) can be very lucrative for f‌irms. Halliburton, a
US-based oil company, received a $7 billion contract to reconstruct Iraqs oil
infrastructure after the Iraq war.
1
Skypower, whose headquarters are in
Canada, concluded a $1.3 billion contract with Uzbekistan in 2018 to build
1000 MW of solar energy production facilities throughout the country.
2
Global f‌irms can benef‌it not only from being awarded investment contracts,
but also operating the resulting facilities, which increases long-term revenues.
However, FDI involves signif‌icant costs (Foley & Manova, 2015, 125
126). Most of these are up-front, f‌ixed costs that often go toward building
production or service facilities. Likewise, various non-economic factors, such
as unstable political situations or weak property rights, can raise the risk of
FDI projects.
3
Most FDI projects only become prof‌itable several years after
the project is completed. Therefore, the signif‌icant up-front costs of FDI, and
the long time horizon of its prof‌itability, prevent many f‌irms from entering the
global market.
Political economy models show that only the most prof‌itable f‌irms can
afford to bear the costs of FDI (Antr`
as & Helpman, 2004;Helpman & Yeaple,
2004;Melitz, 2003). Large f‌irms are often best able to do so. They can provide
differentiated products or deliver skill-intensive services at low prices because
they are able to leverage economies of scale. By contrast, many smaller f‌irms
cannot take advantage of economies of scale and so must sell similar products
at higher prices (Bernard et al., 2003). Ultimately, large f‌irms can monopolize
the market for certain products by undercutting their competitors with low
prices, allowing them to further increase their prof‌its in both foreign and
domestic markets. Consequently, it is believed that only the largest f‌irms that
generate the most prof‌its are able to serve foreign markets through costly FDI.
FDI research has not fully explored the political power of large f‌irms.
4
Firms are not apolitical actors that are insulated from governments
(e.g., Fisman, 2001). Instead, they frequently lobby their government to obtain
preferred policies (Grossman & Helpman, 1994). In turn, many governments
incentivize domestic f‌irms to engage in FDI to boost national economic
performance (Kalinowski & Cho, 2012;Shi, 2015). One of the common
methods of doing so is by making credit easily available through state-owned
banks (Danzman, 2019).
I argue that state-subsidized f‌inancing acts as a f‌inancial incentive for
certain f‌irms to engage in FDI. Beyond just directly reducing the immediate
f‌inancial burdens of FDI, state-subsidized f‌inancing also functions as risk
insurance. Political events, such as contractual breaches and expropriations by
host governments, degrade the value of f‌irmsforeign assets. The home
government can directly cover these losses with access to cheap credit or cash
payments. This insurance reduces the political risks of FDI and thereby
ensures its long-term prof‌itability. Therefore, I expect f‌irms, particularly large
ones, to enhance their government lobbying efforts to secure such
Kim 1001

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT