Pass‐through in a concentrated industry: empirical evidence and regulatory implications

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12168
Published date01 March 2017
Date01 March 2017
AuthorNathan H. Miller,Matthew Osborne,Gloria Sheu
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.48, No. 1, Spring 2017
pp. 69–93
Pass-through in a concentrated industry:
empirical evidence and regulatory
implications
Nathan H. Miller
Matthew Osborne∗∗
and
Gloria Sheu∗∗∗
We estimate pass-through with 30 years of data from the portland cement industry. Robust
econometric evidence supports that fuel cost changes are morethan fully transmitted downstream
in the form of price changes. This validates an implicit pass-through assumption made in recent
academic research and regulatory analyses. We combine the econometric results with estimates
of competitive conduct obtained from the literature to evaluate the incidence of market-based
CO2regulation. Producersbear roughly 11% of the regulatory burden and could be compensated
with 16% of the revenues obtained.
1. Introduction
The distributional consequences of taxation in imperfectly competitive markets depend
on pass-through and markups (Weyl and Fabinger, 2013; Atkin and Donaldson, 2015). This
theoretical result poses a substantial challenge for applied research on incidence: reduced-form
estimates of pass-through are insufficient if firms exercise market power, whereas structural
models that allow for the recovery of markups often rely on tractable functional forms that
predetermine pass-through. This issue is particularly salient for the study of emissions-intensive
industries because production in these sectors often requires investments and fixed costs that
necessitate high markups in equilibrium.
Georgetown University; nhm27@georgetown.edu.
∗∗University of Toronto; matthew.osborne@utoronto.ca.
∗∗∗Depar tment of Justice; gloria.sheu@usdoj.gov.
We havebenefited from conversations with David Atkin, John Asker, Ron Borkovsky, Andrew Ching, Keith Head,Mar
Reguant, and Glen Weyl,as well as the seminar participants at Boston College, Department of Justice Antitrust Division,
London School of Economics, University of British Columbia, UCLA, and University of California, Berkeley. Wethank
Sam Larson, Erika Lim, Conor Ryan, and Jiayi Zhang for research assistance. The views expressed herein are entirely
those of the authors and should not be purported to reflect those of the US Department of Justice.
C2017, The RAND Corporation. 69
70 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
In this article, we estimate pass-through in the portland cement industry using reduced-form
regression techniques. We combine the results with estimates of markups derived from an earlier
study of the industry (Miller and Osborne, 2014) to evaluate the distributional consequences
of market-based regulation that places a price on CO2emissions. The portland cement industry
accounts for roughly 5% of global anthropogenic CO2emissions and also is a source of local
pollutants such as particulate matter and mercury (Van Oss and Padovani, 2003). Market power
arises due to spatial differentiation: cement is transported by truck to ready-mix concrete plants
and large construction sites, and the associated costs typically account for a sizable portion of
purchasers’ total expenditures.
Our regression equation derives from a general class of oligopoly models. We show how
regressors can be constructed in a manner that preserves the oligopoly interactions, even if only
aggregated prices are observed. In our application, we rely on variation in region-specific average
prices over the period 1980–2010. We calculate the fuel costs of each plant based on fossil fuel
prices and kiln technology and estimate pass-through by regressing observed prices on fuel costs
that are averaged to the region level. Unbiasedness is obtained under standard orthogonality
assumptions that are defensible given the institutional details of the empirical setting. To provide
one such detail, there are no viable substitutes for fossil fuel in the production process because
inputs (e.g., limestone and heat) are used in fixed proportions. As such, fuel costs plausibly are
uncorrelated with unobserved costs, especially once plant fixed effects absorb any plant-specific
factors related to the kiln technology.
The primary econometric result is that market-wide cost changes are more than fully passed
through to cement prices. The result is robust across a range of specifications and modelling
choices, and the confidence intervals are sufficiently tight to reject that pass-through is substan-
tially incomplete. Weyl and Fabinger (2013) demonstrate that, in a general symmetric model of
oligopoly, for pass-through to exceed unity it is sufficient that marginal costs are constant, firms
exercise market power, and demand is log-convex. The model provides the testable auxiliary
prediction that competition reduces pass-through under the same conditions. We find support
for this auxiliary prediction in the data, using measures of competition based on the number,
proximity, and capacity of nearby plants. Given the presence of plant fixed effects, identification
of this interactive effect rests on entry, exit, and fluctuations in the diesel price, the last of which
affects transportation costs and the magnitude of localized market power.
We evaluate the incidence of market-based CO2regulation using the Weyl and Fabinger
(2013) model of symmetric oligopoly.The effect of regulation on consumer surplus is determined
by pass-through. The effecton producersurplus depends on pass-through and a conduct parameter
that equals the multiplicative product of firm margins and the elasticity of market demand. Our
econometric estimates inform pass-through but not the conduct parameter. By contrast, recently
estimated structural models of the industry have bearing on the conduct parameter but are
insufficiently flexible to inform pass-through. Thus, wecalculate distributional effects for a range
of pass-through that reflects the confidence intervals obtained in this article, and a range of
conduct parameters that reflects confidence intervals obtained from a bootstrap of the Miller and
Osborne (2014) structural model. At the middle of these distributions, the pass-through that we
estimate implies that cement producers bear 11% of the regulatory burden and could be fully
compensated with 16% of the revenues obtained from regulation.
This counterfactual analysis has limitations, and we highlight three here. First, our approach
does not enable us to put a confidence bound on the harm to producers because there is no
straightforward wayto compute the statistical covariance between pass-through and conduct. Both
theory and our reduced-form results suggest this covariance is positive for pass-through in excess
of unity,and we discuss the implications of such a relationship qualitatively.Second, our approach
does not inform the extent of heterogeneity that arises among producers and consumers. We rely
on the symmetric model because it comports with our econometric estimates, which capture the
average effect of fuel costs on prices. Finally, the results may not convey to other sectors. A new
Working Paper finds that portland cement is one of the few US manufacturing sectors in which
C
The RAND Corporation 2017.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT