Passive vertical integration and strategic delegation

AuthorMatthias Hunold,Konrad Stahl
Published date01 November 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12158
Date01 November 2016
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.47, No. 4, Winter 2016
pp. 891–913
Passive vertical integration and strategic
delegation
Matthias Hunold
and
Konrad Stahl∗∗
With backward acquisitions in their efficient supplier, downstream firms profitably internalize
the effects of their actions on their rivals’ sales, while upstream competition is also relaxed.
Downstream prices increase with passive, yet decrease with controlling acquisition. Passive
acquisition is profitable when controlling acquisition is not. Downstream acquirers strategically
abstain from vertical control, thus delegating commitment to the supplier, and with it high
input prices, allowing them to charge high downstream prices. The effects of passive backward
acquisition arereinforced with the acquisition by severaldownstream firms in the efficient supplier.
The results are sustained when suppliers charge two-part tariffs.
1. Introduction
Partial acquisitions among horizontally and vertically related firms are very common,
although their effects have rarely been analyzed.1We contribute by demonstrating the incentives
Heinrich Heine Universit¨
at D¨
usseldorf, D¨
usseldorf Institute for Competition Economics; hunold@dice.hhu.de.
∗∗University of Mannheim, CEPR, CESifo, and ZEW; kos@econ.uni-mannheim.de.
This research originated from very fruitful discussions with Lars-Hendrik R¨
oller. Financial support from the Deutsche
Forschungsgemeinschaftthrough SFB TR-15 is g ratefullyacknowledged. We benefitted from presentations of this workin
seminars at Athens, Auckland, Bocconi, Florence, Humboldt, Regensburg,and Tilburg Universities; the IFN Stockholm;
at the EARIE and MaCCI Annual Conferences 2012, Rome and Mannheim; the ANR-DFG Annual Workshop 2012,
Toulouse; the CEPR IO meeting 2013, Cyprus; the SFB TR-15 Workshop 2013, Tutzing; and the ACE Annual meeting
2013, Bruxelles. Wethank Kai-Uwe K¨
uhn, Johannes Muthers, VolkerNocke, Fausto Pannunzi, Lars Persson,Patrick Rey,
David Sauer, Yossi Spiegel, Jean Tirole; and especially the Editor, Mark Armstrong, and two referees; Jacques Cr´
emer,
Marco Ottaviani, Nicolas Schutz, and Yaron Yehezkel for constructive comments; and Thorsten Doherr and Christoph
Wolffor competent research assistance.
1The frequency of partial acquisitions in related firms is well documented by Allen and Phillips (2000). They show
that in the United States, 53% of corporate block ownership involves firms in related industries. In the 2014 waveof the
Mannheim Enterprise Panel, we found that of all German firms with more than 20 employees reported in that database
with financial interests in one or more firms in the same NACE two- and three-digit industry,32% and 33% respectively,
held minority stakes. Industries were classified according to NACE—the statistical classification of economic activities
in the European Union. As only “substantive ownership”shares are recorded in that survey, these percentages are a lower
bound.
C2016, The RAND Corporation. 891
892 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
of downstream firms to acquire financial interests in their suppliers, as well as the effects of
these acquisitions on upstream and downstream prices and the profitability of the firms. The
direction of acquisition—backward versus forward—is irrelevant in the conventional models of
full integration. The integrated firm is assumed to own 100% of the assets of both original firms
and to maximize their joint profit. By contrast, the direction of acquisition matters under partial
integration. Moreover, it also matters whether the acquisition is passive or controlling.
Similar to a vertical merger, both passiveand controlling forward integration of an upstream
supplier in its customers tends to induce vertical coordination, by reducing doublemarginalization
and thus downstream prices. Obviously, this is consumer surplus increasing and procompetitive.
By contrast, we show that passive backward integration induces horizontal coordination, exac-
erbates double marginalization, and increases downstream prices, which is consumer surplus
reducing and anticompetitive. We also show that—in contrast to full backward integration—
passive backward integration tends to be profitable for the integrating firms. This provides an
answer to one of the questions addressed in this article, namely, is passive partial backward
integration really as innocent as presently believed, with respect to anticompetitive effects such
as increasing prices or foreclosure?
To derive this answer, we consider a pair of vertically related competitive markets. The
downstream firms produce differentiated products and the upstream firms a homogeneous one.
The upstream firms have different marginal production costs. The downstreamfir ms mayacquire
financial interests in their suppliers, which may be passive or controlling, with passive interests
involving pure cash flow rights; namely, claims only on the target’s profits without controlling its
decisions.
Fixing first the distribution of these interests, we look at the firms’ unrestricted pricing
decisions in both downstream and upstream markets. We concentrate on the case in which
upstream competition is effective in the sense that the efficient supplier’s pricing decision is
restricted by the next-best competitor’s marginal cost. We subsequently explore the downstream
firms’ incentives for backward integration.
Weborrow this interesting and—we feel—empirically relevant setup from Chen (2001), with
the essential difference that we consider the incentives to unilaterally or multilaterally acquire
passive partial, as opposed to controlling full backward financial interests, as well as the effects
of such acquisitions. This difference substantially changes the economics of vertical interaction
between the firms. Weshow that in our model, downstream prices increase with the acquisition of
the typical downstream firm’s passive interests in the efficient supplier; bycontrast, they decrease
with the acquisition of controlling interests. Furthermore, passive partial backward integration is
profitablewhen controlling full backward integration is not. It follows that unlike fully controlling
vertical integration, passive partial backwardinteg ration givesrise to competition policy concerns.
A simple example should convey the intuition for our argument.Let a supplier Uproduce at
zero marginal cost and sell its products to two competing retailers Aand Bat a unit price of 100,
the cost at which each retailer could alternatively procure from a less efficient competitor—or a
competitive fringe. Let retailer Aacquire a noncontrolling financial interest in supplier Uthat
allows it to absorb 25% of U’s profit, whereas Bremains nonintegrated. Accordingly, Aabsorbs
25% of the profit obtained by Ufrom selling goods to B. The margin thus obtained on sales
diverted to its competitor Bincentivizes Ato rais e its price, just as if it had directly acquired a
financial interest in B.
However, with all else given, Ais also incentivized to reduce its price, as for each unit of
input purchased from Uat a nominal price of 100, Aobtains 25% back through its financial
interest in U. This reduces A’s effective unit input price to 75, which, all else given, induces A
to optimally charge a lower price to consumers. The reduction in double marginalization would
thus need to be weighed against A’s incentive to divert sales to B, whereby on balance passive
backward integration could well be procompetitive.
Now, given that the shares of supplier Uacquired by Aare noncontrolling, Ucontinues
to maximize its own profits. Thus far, A’s effective postacquisition unit input price is only 75,
C
The RAND Corporation 2016.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT