Party Competition, Personal Votes, and Strategic Disloyalty in the U.S. States

Date01 December 2021
Published date01 December 2021
DOI10.1177/1065912920953210
Subject MatterArticles
2021, Vol. 74(4) 1024 –1036
https://doi.org/10.1177/1065912920953210
Political Research Quarterly
© 2020 University of Utah
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/1065912920953210
journals.sagepub.com/home/prq
Article
In April of 2019, the New York state legislature passed a
state budget of $175 million. Democratic majorities, in
charge of both the state’s Assembly and Senate for the
first time in nearly a decade, passed the landmark bill that
included reforms to the state’s criminal justice spending
priorities, increases in education spending for schools
in the state’s poorer communities, alterations to transit
pricing in major cities, as well as other modifications
to health care spending and environmental protections.
Governor Cuomo and the majority leaders of both cham-
bers praised the budget as one of the most progressive in
New York’s history. Despite what appears to have been a
significant political victory for the state’s Democrats,
Assemblyman Charles Barron [D-Brooklyn] voted
against his party’s budget, railing that it did too little to
address inequality in the state and failed to fund a state
commission for publicly financed elections. Barron was
one of the only two Democrats to oppose his party’s
budget in the State Assembly.1
For traditional models of spatial voting, such “protest”
votes can be puzzling. However, recent research focusing
on “strategic party disloyalty” offers an explanation for
protest voting that centers on legislators’ efforts to signal
ideological purity to constituents via this type of grand-
standing vote (Kirkland and Slapin 2017, 2018; Slapin
et al. 2018). And recent research on Congress finds that
such “ends against the middle” voting is reasonably prev-
alent in the U.S. Congress (Duck-Mayr and Montgomery
2019). This argument suggests that legislators seeking to
develop a personal vote will occasionally oppose their
own party as part of a symbolic effort to demonstrate
ideological commitment when they can portray their own
party’s legislation as not moving far enough in an ideo-
logical direction. Indeed, Charles Barron, in the wake of
his vote against his own parties’ budget, posted several
videos on his webpage in which he highlighted how the
budget represented a failure to address a racist and
unequal capitalist society, an argument likely to fit well
with his Brooklyn district, but reflecting views to the left
of the Democratic Party mainstream. By voting against
the budget and his own party, he gave himself a prime
opportunity to reiterate his views and to distinguish his
position from that of the party center.2 Barron could use
953210
PRQXXX10.1177/1065912920953210Political Research QuarterlyBurke et al.
research-article2020
1University of Virginia, Charlottesville, USA
2University of Zurich, Switzerland
Corresponding Author:
Justin H. Kirkland, Department of Politics, University of Virginia, S162
Gibson Hall, Charlottesville, VA 22904, USA.
Email: jhk9y@virginia.edu
Party Competition, Personal Votes, and
Strategic Disloyalty in the U.S. States
Richard Burke1, Justin H. Kirkland1, and Jonathan B. Slapin2
Abstract
Legislators will sometimes vote against their party’s position on roll-call votes to differentiate themselves from the
party mainstream and to accrue a “personal vote.” Research suggests that the use of rebellion to generate a personal
vote is more common (1) among majority party members and (2) among ideological extremists. But these majority
party extremists only have a strong incentive to rebel in situations where the accrual of a personal vote is electorally
useful. In this manuscript, we evaluate variation in rebellion rates of state legislators in the United States conditional
on ideological extremism and majority control. Using donation-based measures of ideology and roll call–based
measures of party loyalty over a twenty-year period across more than 30,000 legislators, we find that when legislators
have little incentive to differentiate themselves from their parties, this “strategic” party disloyalty among majority
party ideological extremists is limited. However, when legislators have strong incentives to craft a personal vote,
ideological extremists defect from their party more often than their moderate counterparts. In particular, we find
greater evidence for this type of strategic party disloyalty in states with high intra-party competition and low inter-
party competition and less evidence in states with high inter-party competition.
Keywords
state legislatures, party competition, party loyalty

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT