Partially Revealing Campaign Promises

Published date01 April 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12189
Date01 April 2017
AuthorELENA PANOVA
PARTIALLY REVEALING CAMPAIGN PROMISES
ELENA PANOVA
Toulouse School of Economics, University of Toulouse-1, Capitole
Abstract
Candidates competing for political office give promises to voters. There
are no legal restraints preventing incumbents from breaking their elec-
toral promises. This paper models campaign promises as pure cheap
talk and asks why is it influential. We propose that a candidate’s cam-
paign promises are a partially revealing signal of her policy preference
type. The incumbent’s policy choice is yet another signal of her type.
Policy choice is a costly signal (unlike campaign promises). The in-
cumbent keeps her electoral promises in order to preserve ambiguity
about her type, which is necessary to assemble a winning majority for
reelection. She keeps her promises regardless of information about the
efficiency of different public policies which she receives upon taking
office. Therefore, campaign promises generate inefficiencies in public
policy.
1. Introduction
The candidates competing for office give promises on various policy issues: corporate
taxes, healthcare policy, minimum wage, immigration, gay marriage, abortion, and so.
The winners face no legal restraints preventing them from breaking their word to the
voters. Yet, they deliver most of their promises (Lederman and Pomper 1980; Krukones
1984; Fishel 1985; Budge, Robertson, and Hearl 1987; Petry 1995; Royed and Borrelli
1997). How can we explain this behavior without assuming any direct cost of breaking
promises? Conventional wisdom suggests that incumbents keep their electoral promises
in order to win reelection. However, why do incumbents who keep their promises win
against challengers?
Elena Panova, Toulouse School of Economics, University of Toulouse-1, Capitole, 21 Allee de Brienne,
31000 Toulouse, France (e panova@yahoo.com).
I am grateful to the editor and anonymous referees for their constructive comments and insightful
suggestions. I also thank Francis Bloch, Oliver Board, Stephen Coate, Gary Charness, Stefan Krasa,
Jean-Marie Lozachmeur, Nicolas Marceau, John Morgan, Michael Peters, Julia Shvets, and Jean Ti-
role for valuable feedback on earlier versions of this paper. My work has benefited from attention
of seminar participants at New Economic School, Universit´
edeMontr
´
eal, Universit´
eduQu
´
ebec `
a
Montr´
eal, Simon Fraser University, University of Victoria, University of Pittsburgh, and participants of
Annual Meetings of the American Political Science Association, the Canadian Economic Theory Con-
ference, and the Canadian Economic Association, and the Third World Congress of the Game Theory
Society.
Received September 6, 2014; Accepted December 20, 2015.
C2016Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Public Economic Theory, 19 (2), 2017, pp. 312–330.
312
Partially Revealing Campaign Promises 313
A possible reason is that the voters deduce some information about an incumbent’s
policy preferences first, from her electoral promises (pure cheap talk), and then from
her policy choice (costly signal). Due to the electoral competition, the incumbent’s
promises reveal her policy preferences to a large extent. In order to win a majority for
reelection, the incumbent has to avoid any further revelation. Therefore, she keeps her
promises.
We formalize this argument by modeling first the electoral competition, and second
the incumbent’s policy choice in face of upcoming reelection (earlier literature models
these two stages of political process independently; more on this in Section 2).1
We consider a game with two successive elections: an open seat and the incumbent-
challenger.2In each election, two candidates with private information about their policy
preferences (types) compete for office via simple majority vote. The winner takes office
and chooses public policy. A voter votes for the candidate who is more likely to share
the voter’s preferences, conditional on the voter’s information.
Policy space and preferences are modeled as in Maskin and Tirole (2014).3The
voters are divided in minorities benefiting from different public policies. Public policy
benefiting one minority is costly to other minorities (no minority is “median,” unlike
in spacial models). Choosing public policy is equivalent to choosing the beneficiaries
among the minorities.4A candidate for office has the same policy preferences as one of
the minorities—which minority is her private information.
The game proceeds as follows. First, there is an open-seat election. Two candidates
for office give campaign promises regarding the policies they would undertake if in
office. A candidate can give any promises she wishes at no cost, and she has no com-
mitment to keep any of her promises if in office. The winning candidate chooses pub-
lic policy and runs for reelection against an “untried” challenger. The winner of the
incumbent-challenger election chooses any public policy she wishes.
Proposition 1 shows that this game has an equilibrium with partially revealing
campaign promises. In this equilibrium, the voters deduce that a candidate’s preferred
policies are among those she is promising. A candidate promises to implement her pre-
ferred policies plus some other policies, so as to assemble a winning majority of voters on
her side. If in office, she has to keep these voters on her side in order to win reelection.
So, she delivers the promised policies.
Because campaign promises are cheap talk, the game has equilibria in which the
voters ignore campaign messages and the candidates “babble” in various ways. We filter
these equilibria away by a refinement based on neologisms. Proposition 2 shows that
campaign promises are partially revealing in any refined equilibrium.
Proposition 3 shows that campaign promises generate inefficiencies. The reason
is that the incumbent receives information about the efficiencies of different policies
upon achieving office. However, she keeps her promises regardless of this information.
The paper is organized as follows. The next section reviews related literature.
Section 3 presents the model. Section 4 describes an equilibrium with partially
1The models of electoral competition do not study the winner’s policy choice, while the models of
electoral accountability have no actual campaign stage.
2We focus on the game with two elections which is just sufficient for our purposes. A finite horizon of
our game makes it apparent that our argument is different from the reputational argument proposed
in the literature.
3This approach is most convenient to model the candidates’ campaign promises and the incumbent’s
policy choice as signals.
4For example, cutting college tuitions is equivalent to benefiting young voters, overhauling immigra-
tion policy is equivalent to benefiting Hispanic voters, and so on.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT