OPTIMAL TIMING AND TERMS IN A VERTICAL MERGER WITH TWO SOURCES OF UNCERTAINTY

AuthorSijia Zhang,Zhuming Chen,Tao Lin
Date01 May 2020
Published date01 May 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12209
The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XLIII, No. 2 Pages 345372 Summer 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jfir.12209
OPTIMAL TIMING AND TERMS IN A VERTICAL MERGER WITH TWO
SOURCES OF UNCERTAINTY
Zhuming Chen
Sun Yatsen University
Sijia Zhang
Credit Agricole Corporate and Investment Bank
Tao Lin
University of Hong Kong
Abstract
In this article we provide the optimal timing and equilibrium terms of a vertical
merger with two sources of uncertainty in the production chain, namely, marginal
cost of raw material and price level of final product. By eliminating monopoly power
and transaction cost in the production process between upstream and downstream
firms, a vertical merger can increase social welfare, which is consistent with the
literature. The optimal threshold of a vertical merger is negatively correlated with
transaction cost in the intermediate product market. Vertical mergers also accelerate
when merging provides natural hedging for the postmerger firm, that is, when the
correlation between the two uncertainties increases.
JEL Classification: D23, G13, G34
I. Introduction
Mergers and acquisitions (M&As) are important and efficient strategies for firms to use
to increase their capital, gain access to technology, and improve their competitiveness.
Mitchell and Mulherin (1996) demonstrate that they are the least costly means for firms
to respond to industry shocks. Although there is a considerable amount of research in
financial economics on M&As, including vertical mergers, how different factors affect
the optimal timing and equilibrium terms of vertical mergers remains unclear.
Transaction cost theory, which is one widely used approach to study vertical mergers,
suggests that eliminating transaction cost is an important incentive for vertical
integration. However, further theoretical work is required.
There are many examples demonstrating the benefit of lower transaction costs
and associated risks from vertical integration. For example, hot metal is produced in
blast furnaces and is used to make crude steel. Trading of hot metal in its liquid form at
about 2,500 degrees exists but is very rare. Vertical integration of the two processes
The authors thank Yan Zeng and an anonymous reviewer for the helpful suggestions.
345
© 2020 The Southern Finance Association and the Southwestern Finance Association
can reduce the negotiation costs and exploitation risk between these tightly bound pairs
of buyers and sellers (Stuckey and White 1993).
Apart from reducing costs, vertical integration may enable firms to capture
more economic surplus. For example, highquality needle coke is the main material for
the production of large (super) highpower graphite electrodes, which in turn are
needed in electric steelmaking. Because of increased market demand for highquality
steel in China, the demand for graphite electrodes and highquality needle coke has
gone up. At the same time, most domestic needle coke could not meet the quality
requirement in key performance measures.
In 2017, Fangda Carbon New Material Co. Ltd. (Fangda), a company that
produces graphiterelated products, acquired a 51% stake in CChem (Jiangsu) Needle
Coke Technology Co. Ltd, a highquality needle coke producer whose production
technology and equipment plan are from Nippon Steel & Sumitomo Metal Corporation
(NSSMC), a world leader in the field and CChems parent company at the time.
1
The
move allowed Fangda to expand into the upstream industry value chain, improve its
technical position, ensure a stable supply of highquality material, reduce reliance on
imports, and save on procurement costs.
In this article we extend the literature by building an equilibrium model to
study the impact of monopoly power and transaction cost on the timing and terms of a
vertical merger between upstream and downstream firms. In our model, the upstream
firm produces an intermediate product that the downstream firm uses as input to the
final product. The upstream firm has monopoly power to set the price of this
intermediate product, whereas the downstream firm faces perfect competition in the
final product market. A production transaction cost is involved in the intermediate
product market that has a constant component and a variable component proportional
to the sales of the intermediate product.
Based on Lambrecht (2004) and Tarsalewska (2015), we construct a real
option model in which the downstream firm has a permanent American call option to
merge with the upstream firm, and the upstream firm has an option to sell out. Our
model examines how the motivation of eliminating transaction cost and monopoly
power through vertical merger balances out the merger cost. Before the merger, the
monopolistic upstream firm sets the price above the economically efficient price,
which lowers the quantity of intermediate goods traded and consequently reduces final
output from the downstream firm. In addition, the transaction cost in the procurement
process further creates economic losses. Vertical integration allows the integrated firm
to capture bigger amount of economic surplus, which can be shared between the two
firms.
We also examine how comovement in different uncertainties affects the
merger decision. In our model, the upstream firm faces the random production cost of
the intermediate product, and the downstream firm faces the random price of the final
product. The two prices may correlate differently across industries. For example,
industries that require imports from other countries may have a lower correlation
1
Progress Report on CChem share acquisition, Fangda Carbon Press Release No. 2017028.
346 The Journal of Financial Research

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT