Optimal regulation of network expansion

Date01 March 2018
Published date01 March 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12217
AuthorGijsbert Zwart,Bert Willems
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.49, No. 1, Spring 2018
pp. 23–42
Optimal regulation of network expansion
Bert Willems
and
Gijsbert Zwart ∗∗
We model the regulation of irreversible capacity expansion by a firm with private information
about capacity costs, where investments are financed from the firm’s cash flows and demand is
stochastic. The optimal mechanism is implemented by a revenue tax that increases with the price
cap. If the asymmetric information has large support, then the optimal mechanism consists of
a laissez-faire regime for low-cost firms. That is, the firm’s price cap corresponds to that of an
unregulated monopolist, and it is not taxed. This “maximal distortion at the top” is necessary to
provide information rents, as direct subsidies are not feasible.
1. Introduction
Since the nineties, many regulated network industries switched from cost-plus (or rate-
of-return) to incentive regulation, often under some form of price cap regulation. This switch
was motivated by the fear that cost-plus regulated firms would “gold-plate” their networks and
overinvestin capital (Averchand Johnson, 1962) and the realization that a price cap provides high-
powered incentives for cost-efficiency (Cabral and Riordan, 1989).1However, in recent years,
stakeholders have argued that with high-powered incentive regulation, firms postpone socially
efficient investments in durable assets, especiallyin risky environments, and that a different form
of regulation is necessary. For instance, in response to large investment needs, the UK Office of
Gas and Electricity Markets, Ofgem, modernized its price cap mechanism by explicitlytaking into
account these investmentneeds.2European energy directives allow specific networkinvestments to
Tilburg Universityand Toulouse School of Economics; bwillems@tilburguniversity.edu.
∗∗University of Groningen and Tilburg University, Tilec; g.t.j.zwart@r ug.nl.
We have benefited from useful comments from seminar participants at Chulalongkorn University, June 2017, Ecoles
de Mines de Paris, March 2013, Norwegian University of Science and Technology,June 2016, Thammassat University,
June 2017, Tilburg University, April 2014, ToulouseUniversity, January 2017, UCL Louvain La Neuve, December 2016,
University of Basel, February 2017, the Symposium in Honour of Jean Tirole, The Hague, December 2014, the IFN
Conference on the Performance of Electricity Markets, Stockholm, July 2014, the IAEE conference, Singapore, June
2017, and from discussions with Peter Broer, Claude Crampes, SteffenHoer nig, Bruno Julien, Thomas-Olivier L´
eautier,
and Thomas Tanger˚
as. We also thank two anonymous referees and Mark Armstrong, the Editor, for their insightful
comments.
1See, for instance, Sappington (2002) for an overview of the perceiveddrawbacks of rate-of-return regulation.
2The United Kingdom was one of the first countries to introduce the RPI-X price cap model where the caps grows
with the Retail Price Index (RPI) minus expected efficiency savingsX. (Beesley and Littlechild, 1989). After a review, a
C2018 The Authors The RAND Journal of Economics published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc. on behalf of The RAND
Corporation. This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-
NoDerivs License, which permits use and distribution in any medium, provided the original work is properlycited, the
use is non-commercial and no modifications or adaptations are made. 23
24 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
be exempted from regulation in order to foster investmentsif uncertainty is large.3For the telecom
sector, the European Telecommunications Network Operators’ Association, ETNO, recommends
relaxing access regulation, as it sees it as the main reason for European infrastructure investments
lagging those in the United States (Williamson,Lewin, and Wood,2016).4Also, academic scholars
recognize that implementing price cap regulation is challenging for durableinvestments and when
uncertainty is important (Guthrie, 2006; Armstrong and Sappington, 2007).
In this article, we contribute to this debate by studying the optimal regulation of capacity
investments in a dynamic setting in which investment prospects are uncertain. For this, we
consider a regulated private firm that has to gradually expand its networkto cope with a growth in
demand for network access, needs to fund its investmentsfrom operating profits, and has superior
information on investments costs. The regulator contracts with the firm about when it should
expand capacity (and when it would be better to delay), at which price the capacity should be
sold, and which fraction of its revenues it may keep. The regulator acts as a social planner and
maximizes the expected discounted sum of consumers’ surplus and the firm’s profit.
In the optimal regulatory mechanism, existing capacity is always used efficiently: prices
for network access are equal to the short-run marginal cost of transportation as long as there is
spare capacity,and prices are above marginal cost when there is congestion. Capacity is expanded
whenever the price for capacity reaches a threshold value. This price threshold increases with
investment costs and is always higher than under the first-best symmetric information optimum
with demand uncertainty. Hence, investments are delayed.5
As we assume that the firm does not receive subsidies, investmentcosts need to be paid from
market revenues. However, any operating profits that remain after those costs have been paid for
could be taxed by the regulator. Under optimal regulation, the regulator does not tax the firms
that reveal to be relatively efficient, whereas the tax rate for the less efficient firms increases with
their levels of inefficiency. Those low tax rates are necessary to provide the efficient firms with
information rents.
If the information asymmetry between the regulator and the firm has large support, then
the relatively efficient firms will be allowed to invest as if they were unregulated monopolists, as
this provides the largest possible information rents. Hence, a laissez-faire regime is optimal for
those firms. In the case with small support, the regulator will bunch the more efficient firms and
require identical investment levels for these. Hence, optimal regulation no longer results in an
equilibrium with full separation of types.
In our model, demand growth is not fully predictable(i.e., stochastic) and network investmentsare
sunk. Hence, the firm is continuously forecasting demand and balancing the benefits of expanding
capacity now (and obtaining additional revenue)and delaying investments (and obtaining superior
information about future demand). In other words, it needs to take into account the real-option
value of investments (Dixit and Pindyck, 1994). McDonald and Siegel (1986) show that an
unregulated monopolist delays investments under uncertainty, and Pindyck (1988) extends this
result to a continuous investment model. Although first-best investment also involves a delay,
under monopoly,this delay is longer. If a regulator would try to correct this situation with only the
price cap instrument at its disposal, then the first-best outcome cannot be reached (Dobbs, 2004),
as one instrument is used for two goals: efficient investments ex ante and optimal consumption
new set of regulatory principles was introduced,the RIIO (Revenue =Incentives + Innovation + Outputs) model. This is
still a form of price regulation, but includes output obligations and additional funds for experimentation (Ofgem, 2010b).
3Exemptions can be granted if among others “the level of risk attached to the investmentis such that the investment
would not take place unless an exemption was granted” (Regulation EC 714/2009, Art.17, and Directive 2009/73/EC,
Art. 36). Until 2015, there were 35 exemption requests, most of which were(partially) granted.
4In contrast to the energy sector, the European Commission does not allowregulatory exemptions for the telecom-
munication sector and successfully appealed the decision of the German government to grant Deutsche Telekom an
exemption (Commission v.Germany 2009, case number C-424/07, the European Court of Justice).
5Note that the first-best investment expansion plan already delaysinvestments to take into account the real-option
value of network expansion.
C
The RAND Corporation 2018.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT