Optimal Prevention for Multiple Risks

Published date01 September 2017
AuthorRichard Peter,Christophe Courbage,Henri Loubergé
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12105
Date01 September 2017
©2015 The Journal of Risk and Insurance. Vol.84, No. 3, 899–922 (2017).
DOI: 10.1111/jori.12105
Optimal Prevention for Multiple Risks
Christophe Courbage
Henri Louberg´
e
Richard Peter
Abstract
This article analyzes optimal prevention in a situation of multiple, possi-
bly correlated risks. We focus on probability reduction (self-protection) so
that correlation becomes endogenous. If prevention concerns only one risk,
introducing a second exogenous risk increases the level of prevention expen-
ditures, even if correlation is negative. If prevention expenditures may be
invested for both risks, a substitution effect arises. Under nonincreasing re-
turns on self-protection, we find that increased dependence increases aggre-
gate prevention expenditures, but not necessarily prevention expenditures
for each risk due to differences in prevention efficiency. Similar results are
found when considering changes in the severity of losses. Consequently,the
comparative statics emphasize global effects versus allocation effects.Our re-
sults have strong policy implications, considering the numerous mandatory
safety measures introduced by governments over the past years.
Introduction
Individuals and firms face multiple risks. Some of them are independent but others are
dependent. For example, the risk of damage to the roof is often associated to the risk of
flooding; the risk of releasing hazardous waste in the environment may be associated
to the risk of suffering virus attacks on the information system; the risk of workers’
injuries is known to be negatively correlated with the credit risk of consumers due to
Christophe Courbage is at The Geneva Association and the Haute Ecole de Gestion de Genève,
University of Applied Sciences Western Switzerland (HES-SO). Henri Louberg´
e is at the Uni-
versity of Geneva and Swiss Finance Institute. Richard Peter is at the Department of Finance,
Henry B. Tippie College of Business, University of Iowa. Peter can be contacted via e-mail:
richard-peter@uiowa.edu. Wewould like to thank participants in the 41st Seminar of the Euro-
pean Group of Risk and Insurance Economists in St. Gallen and particularly Harris Schlesinger;
participants in the American Risk and Insurance Association Annual Meeting 2014 in Seattle
and particularly Carole Bernard; participants in the 13th Louis-Andr´
eG
´
erard-Varet Meeting
in Public Economics at the University of Aix-Marseille and particularly Mukul Tyagi; and
seminar participants at the Economics Research Seminar, University of Geneva, the Journ´
ees
Internationales du Risque in Niort, the Economics and Finance Visiting Speaker Series at the
University of Guelph and the RMI Speaker Series at St. John’s University in New York for
valuable comments and discussions.
899
900 The Journal of Risk and Insurance
their common link to the business cycle. Some of the risks may be avoided by taking
radical measures, for example, giving up the pleasure of skiing to avoid the risk of
a ski accident, or giving up the development of a new product to avoid potential
product liability suits. When the risks cannot, or should not, be avoided they may be
managed by prevention and loss reduction measures or transferred to an insurer. The
article focuses on prevention as a risk management tool.
Prevention is an ex ante activity that reduces the probability of a loss.1The economic
analysis of prevention started with the seminal work of Ehrlich and Becker (1972) and
has led since then to a flourishing literature (Courbage, Rey, and Treich, 2013). But,
the canonical model, developed along several dimensions, assumes that the decision
maker (DM) faces only one risk to be mitigated using prevention measures, such as
investing in fire-proof materials to reduce the probability of fire, or investing in locks
and alarms to reduce the probability of burglary. Given that firms and individuals face
multiple risks, the question we ask in this article is how the decision to prevent one
risk interacts with the decision to prevent other risks. More particularly, we wonder
how the characteristics of the multiple risks and the efficiency of alternative preven-
tion instruments influence the decision to invest in a specific portfolio of prevention
measures. For instance, if we consider two risks and if the dependence between the
two risks increases, will the DM increase his total investment and the level of both
prevention activities? How will he alter the composition of his portfolio of prevention
measures? Our analysis can also help to predict the effect of imposing mandatory
prevention expenditures for one risk on the decision to prevent other risks.
While the literature on economic decisions in a multiple-risk setting is quite abundant,
only a few articles have recently addressed the study of self-protection in the pres-
ence of other risks.2These articles look at either the relation between self-protection
and risk aversion in the presence of an independent zero-mean background risk
(Dachraoui et al., 2004) or the impact of an independent zero-mean background
risk on self-protection activities in a one-period model (Lee, 2012) or a two-period
model (Eeckhoudt, Huang, and Tzeng, 2012; Courbage and Rey, 2012; Wang and
Li, forthcoming). Our article differs markedly from the above literature in three
ways. First, we allow for nonzero correlation between the different sources of risk.
This is motivated, among other things, by recent empirical evidence (Sun and Frees,
2013). Second, we also consider the decision to prevent both risks simultaneously,
and not merely the influence of the second risk on optimal prevention for the first
risk. Third, we derive policy implications from our analysis by investigating the
impact of exogenous changes in the level of prevention for one risk on the optimal
self-protection investment for the other risk. This allows us to assess the side effects
of the numerous mandatory safety measures introduced by governments and
1Following Ehrlich and Becker’s (1972) terminology, this activity is also referred to as self-
protection. Throughout the article, we use both terms synonymously.
2Note, however, the contributions of Briys, Schlesinger, and von der Schulenburg (1991) and
Schlesinger (1992) considering the reliability of prevention expenses. There is only one risk
in the endowment, but the possible failure of prevention measures introduces an additional
(multiplicative) risk.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT