Optimal growth when consumption takes time

Published date01 September 2020
AuthorThi‐Do‐Hanh Nguyen,Cuong Le Van,Thai Ha‐Huy
Date01 September 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12467
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:14421461.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet1442
|
© 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC
Received: 18 October 2019
|
Accepted: 22 July 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12467
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Optimal growth when consumption
takes time
Thai HaHuy
1,2
|Cuong Le Van
3
|ThiDoHanh Nguyen
4
1
EPEE, University of Evry, University Paris
Saclay, Évry, France
2
TIMAS, Thang Long University, Évry, France
3
IPAG Business School, Paris School of
Economics, CNRS, TIMAS, Paris, France
4
Vietnam Maritime University, 484 Lach
Tray, Hai Phong, Vietnam
Correspondence
Thai HaHuy, EPEE, University of Evry,
University ParisSaclay, Évry, France.
Email: thai.hahuy@univ-evry.fr
Funding information
Labex MMEDII, Grant/Award Number:
ANR11LBX002301
Abstract
This article analyzes a onesector growth model
where the consumption takes time. When the con-
sumption takes time, the consumption set is compact
and we meet satiety. However, we prove that dy-
namic constraints are binding. This result is crucial to
prove that, under wellknown assumptions in mac-
roeconomic dynamic programming, the optimal path
is monotonic and always converges to a unique
nontrivial steady state as in the case where con-
sumption is timeless.
1|INTRODUCTION
Many wellknown economic models are based on the assumptions that consumption is in-
stantaneous, that is, it does not take time. In the reality, this assumption is not plausible. In the
past or even today, it took people time to wash clothes or to prepare the meals. Even with the
invention of new machines and technologies, there are activities which cannot be reduced in
time, for example, watching a match of soccer or listening to Beethoven's symphony.
Economic agents must always make the tradeoff between the time devoted for the production,
and the time for leisure. The consumption time constraint was first formally introduced by Gossen
(1983) and much later generalized by Becker (1965) in his famous contribution to the theory of time
allocation. Recently, TranNam and Pham (2014) consider the question with a general equilibrium
approach. Le Van, TranNam, Pham, and Nguyen (2018) extend this model to a general equilibrium
model with many goods and many heterogeneous economic agents. In their article, consumption
itself takes time. A typical household is subject to a financial constraint and a time constraint as
well. They show that the economy possesses at least one autarkic Walrasian equilibrium.
In our knowledge, though the problem is well analyzed in static economy, there is no theo-
retical research in a dynamic framework. To give a response for this gap, in this paper, we consider
aonesector growth model, in which consumption is itself time consuming. At each period, the
agent must share her/his available amount of time between consuming and working.
In this case, the consumption set is compact, that is, there is a satiation point while in the
usual models where consuming is timeless the consumption is the positive cone and we have no
satiation point. That is the main difference. However, we prove that all the dynamic constraints
are binding in our model. This result is crucial to prove that, under wellknown assumptions in
macroeconomic dynamic programming, such as concavity of the production and utility func-
tions, and complementarity between capital and labor, the optimal path is monotonic and
converges to a unique nontrivial steady state as in the case where consumption is timeless. That
is our main result.
1
We mention that the steadystate capital stock is lower than the one
obtained in economies where consumption is timeless.
The effects of incorporating an explicit time for consumption in other classes of dynamic
models would be worthwhile to investigate in future work, including for models of pollution
and growth (e.g., Ghosh, Barman, & Gupta, 2020), dynamic allocation of government ex-
penditures (e.g., Fan, Pang, & Pestieau, 2020; Le Van, NguyenVan, BarbierGauchard, &
Le, 2019), or impact of social capital on growth Le Van, Nguyen, Nguyen, and Simioni (2018),
and other dynamic models.
The article is organized as follows. Section 2describes the model. Section 3.2 presents the
indirect utility function and a modified optimization problem which is equivalent to the initial one.
Section 3.4 studies the main properties of the optimal paths. The proofs are given in the appendix.
2|FUNDAMENTALS
Time is discrete. The production requires physical capital and labor. The utility of the agent
depends only on the consumption which takes time. We assume that in each period, the total
amount of time of the agent is inelastic, and is divided into two parts: the first part is devoted for
the production, and the second part for the consumption.
At period
t
, given capital ktand labor which is measured by the labor time
l
t
, the production is
YFkl=(,)
.
ttt
Let
≤≤δ
01
be the depreciation rate of the physical capital. The dynamics of the accumulation
of the capital stocks is
kδkI=(1)+
,
ttt+1
where Itis the investment at time
t
. It is worth noting that we do not impose that
δ
is strictly
positive.
Given the maximal supply of labor time
L
and the working time
l
t
, the available time for
consumption is Ll
. Hence, there are two constraints for the consumers, the resource con-
straint and the time constraint:
cIY
ac L l
+,
,
tt t
tt
1
The results of this model are similar to those obtained from a onesector growth model with elastic labor, see, for
example, Le Van and Vailakis (2004).
HAHUY ET AL.
|
1443

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT