Optimal Design of the Attribution of Pension Fund Performance to Employees

AuthorHeinz Müller,David Schiess
Published date01 June 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1539-6975.2013.01516.x
Date01 June 2014
©
DOI: 10.1111/j.1539-6975.2013.01516.x
431
OPTIMAL DESIGN OF THE ATTRIBUTION OF PENSION
FUND PERFORMANCE TO EMPLOYEES
Heinz M ¨
uller
David Schiess
ABSTRACT
The article analyzes risk sharing in a defined contribution pension fund in
continuous time. According to a prespecified attribution scheme, the interest
rate paid on the employees’ accounts is a linear function of the fund’s invest-
ment performance. For each attribution scheme, the pension fund maximizes
the expected utility and the employees derive utility from their savings ac-
counts. It turns out that all Pareto-optimal attribution schemes are character-
ized by the same optimal participation rate. Wederive the total welfare gain
that installs from replacing no participation with optimal participation. This
welfare gain can be quantified and is substantial for reasonable parameter
values.
INTRODUCTION
In pension finance one must distinguish between defined benefit and defined con-
tribution plans. In a defined benefit plan, benefits are defined in advance and the
plan sponsor and the employees must adjust their contributions. In the literature,
optimal investment strategies for defined benefit plans are treated by Haberman and
Sung (1994), Boulier, Trussant, and Florens (1995), Cairns (2000), and Josa-Fombellida
and Rincon-Zapatero (2006) among others. Furthermore, the articles by Wilkie(1985),
Sharpe and Tint (1990), Keel and M¨
uller (1995), and Leippold, Trojani, and Vanini
(2004) deal with portfolio optimization in the asset–liability context. Since the plan
sponsor has to bear substantial financial and actuarial risk and since the valuation
of accrued retirement benefits of employees changing their plan is difficult, defined
benefit plans have become less and less popular. In a defined contribution plan in
the narrow sense, the accrued retirement benefits of employees are invested and the
positive or negative fund return is fully attributed to the employees’ accounts. At
retirement each employee obtains the final amount from his account either as a cash
payment or a corresponding pension. However, there is a wide span of different
Heinz M¨
uller and David Schiess are at Group for Mathematics and Statistics, University of
St. Gallen, Bodanstrasse 6, 9000 St. Gallen, Switzerland. The authors can be contacted via
e-mail: heinz.mueller@unisg.ch and david.schiess@unisg.ch, respectively. We would like to
thank Dr.Roger Baumann for his valuable input and the two anonymous referees for their very
constructive advice. We also gratefully acknowledge financial support from the University of
St. Gallen’s research program “Wealth and Risk.”
The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 2013, Vol. 81, No. 2, 431–468
432 THE JOURNAL OF RISK AND INSURANCE
defined contribution plans. On the one hand, there exist pure defined contribution
plans like the U.S. 401(k) plans where the employee is free to choose an individ-
ual investment policy. The pension fund consequently bears no financial risk at all
and acts only as a broker between employees and financial and life insurance mar-
kets. Hence, employees may be considered as individual investors. Authors dealing
with this topic in continuous time are Merton (1969), Adler and Dumas (1983), and
Gao (2008, 2009); in discrete time there are articles by Solnik (1978) and Haberman
and Vigna (2002) among others. On the other hand, there exist defined contribution
pension plans with certain guaranteed benefits. The plan sponsor bears substantial
financial risk in order to protect employees against fluctuations of financial markets.
For example, in the mandatory part of Swiss pension funds, the interest paid on the
employees’ accounts may depend on the financial situation and the recent perfor-
mance of the fund, but it has a lower bound fixed by central authorities. As this
minimum interest rate is typically above the riskless interest rate we will model the
rate attributed to the employees’ accounts as the riskless interest rate plus a premium.
However, on top of this, the majority of the Swiss pension funds let their employees
participate in the fund’s investment performance in some way. The overmandatory
part allows them to go below the minimum rate in case of bad investment perfor-
mances. Inspired by these facts, we will assume that the total rate attributed to the
employees’ accounts consists of a premium in addition to the riskless interest rate
and participation in the fund’s investment performance. At retirement, the accounts
are transformed into benefit streams. Of course, in such a framework the value of the
assets may differ from the present value of the liabilities. In the literature, Boulier,
Huang, and Taillard (2001) and Deelstra, Graselli, and Koehl (2003, 2004) analyze
a defined contribution plan providing a guarantee. This article concentrates on the
optimal design of the attribution of the pension fund performance to its employ-
ees. If a pension plan increases the funding ratio (ratio of the value of assets to the
present value of net obligations) during prospering financial markets and decreases
it in declining financial markets, then a risk transfer between different generations
of employees can be established. This idea was formalized by Baumann and M ¨
uller
(2008). In their model they introduced an intertemporal risk transfer by assuming
that the rate attributed to the employees’ accounts depends on the funding ratio but
not directly on the fund’s recent investment performance. In this way the attribution
of investment performance is flattened over time. They showed that in such a frame-
work the pension fund can choose investment policies such that all employees would
be worse off if they acted as individual investors. Furthermore, there are articles
deriving optimal investment strategies for defined contribution plans that put the
funding ratio into the focus of the optimization like Browne (1997), Denzler, M¨
uller,
and Scherer (2001), and M ¨
uller and Baumann (2006). In contrast to these articles,
the liabilities in the papers by M ¨
uller and Baumann (2008) and Baumann and M ¨
uller
(2008) are not exogeneous. Baumann and M ¨
uller (2008) model the return attributed to
the employees’ accrued retirement benefits as a function of the funding ratio. In this
article, we analyze the dependency on the fund’s investment performance. A similar
idea has already been pursued in the work of Baumann (2005). In this article, however,
we get closed-form solutions by restricting the fund’s performance attribution to lin-
ear schemes. Substantial welfare gains result even for this special class of attribution
schemes.
OPTIMAL DESIGN OF THE PENSION FUNDS PERFORMANCE ATTRIBUTION 433
This article deals with financial risk sharing between the defined contribution plan
sponsor and the employees in continuous time. We assume that the rate attributed
to the employees’ accounts consists of a premium in addition to the riskless interest
rate and a linear participation in the fund’s investment performance. The attribution
scheme is part of the institutional setup and can be characterized by the premium and
the participation rate. One of the main purposes of the article is to find Pareto-optimal
attribution schemes. Given an attribution scheme, the pension fund maximizes its
expected utility by choosing a corresponding investment policy. Hence, for each
attribution scheme a corresponding expected utility is obtained. This defines the
indirect utility function of the pension fund on the set of attribution schemes. Given the
investment policies of the pension fund, one may calculate the expected utility of the
employees for each attribution scheme. In this way,the indirect utility function of the
employees can be derived as well. The set of Pareto-optimal attribution schemes
are calculated and it is shown that all Pareto-optima are characterized by the same
participation rate. Since the optimal participation rate is constant, there is a conflict
of interests about the premium only. The specific choice of the premium depends on
the interaction of employees, the firm or institution attached to the pension fund,
and the regulator. On the one hand, the premium should attain a level such that an
employee is better off as a member of the fund than as an individual investor using
the Merton solution. On the other hand, the premium should be low enough to ensure
financial stability of the pension fund. We show that such levels for the premium can
be attained for reasonable parameter values. Furthermore, a formula for the optimal
participation rate is derived. Afterward, we define the welfare of the pension fund
and the employees, respectively, by making use of appropriate certainty equivalents.
Finally, a comparison of optimal participation and no participation shows that there
is a substantial welfare gain for reasonable parameter values.
The article is organized as follows. The second section presents the model setup by
defining the financial market as well as the objective function of both the pension
fund and the employees. Furthermore, linear attribution schemes are introduced and
the evolution of assets and liabilities are developed, which taken together yield the
dynamics of the funding ratio. In the third section, we maximize the expected utility
of the pension fund for a given attribution scheme, which leads to a constant optimal
investment strategy. We discuss the optimal investment rule and close the section
with the derivation of the optimally controlled funding ratio dynamics. In the fourth
section, we derive the indifference curves of the pension fund and the employees,
respectively, which leads to a discussion of risk-adjusted rates of return. The fifth
section then presents the result that there is a unique Pareto-optimal participation
rate α(0, 1). The Pareto-optimal investment strategy is derived by exploiting this
participation rate. The section closes with a discussion of the parameter sensitivities
of optimal participation and investment. The sixth section then narrows the set of
Pareto-efficient attribution schemes by imposing individual rationality of the em-
ployees and financial stability of the pension fund. The seventh section first defines
the welfare of the pension fund and the employees by making use of appropriate
certainty equivalents. Following this, we derive the welfare gain that results if no
participation is replaced with optimal participation. It is shown that this welfare gain
is substantial for reasonable parameter values. Finally,the eighth section summarizes
and presents the main conclusions.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT