Optimal age‐dependent income taxation in a dynamic extensive model: The case for negative participation tax on young people

Published date01 September 2020
AuthorYoshihiro Takamatsu,Takao Kataoka
Date01 September 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12421
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:13381367.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet1338
|
© 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Received: 27 May 2019
|
Accepted: 2 December 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12421
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Optimal agedependent income taxation in a
dynamicextensivemodel:Thecasefornegative
participation tax on young people
Takao Kataoka
1
|
Yoshihiro Takamatsu
2
1
Faculty of Commerce, Waseda
University, Tokyo, Japan
2
Department of Economics, Faculty of
Humanities and Social Sciences,
Shizuoka University, Shizuoka, Japan
Correspondence
Yoshihiro Takamatsu, Department of
Economics, Faculty of Humanities and
Social Sciences, Shizuoka University,
836 Ohya, Surugaku, Shizuoka
4228529, Japan.
Email: takamatsu.yoshihiro@shizuoka.
ac.jp
Funding information
Japan Society for the Promotion of
Science, Grant/Award Numbers:
15K17073, 19K01717
Abstract
We consider optimal agedependent income taxation in a
dynamic model where the laborleisurechoiceisthe
extensive margin, each household faces idiosyncratic
shocks to labor productivity and a pecuniary cost to work,
and there is no insurance market against the shocks. We
show that the wellknown property of the optimal
participation tax rate in the static model continues to hold
in our dynamic economy, that is, the participation tax rates
for some income groups with low consumption are likely
negative. In dynamic models, the optimal participation tax
rate depends on age and on labor income. Our numerical
simulations suggest that a negative participation tax should
be restricted to young households.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The optimal income taxation literature has developed models to analyze the design of income
tax/transfer programs. Following the seminal paper of Mirrlees (1971), many studies have
focused exclusively on the intensive labor margin; in other words, households choose their
hours of work or intensity of work. In such a framework, negative marginal tax rates can never
be optimal, ruling out inwork credits.
Much recent literature has emphasized the role of the extensive margin. In the extensive labor
margin, households choose whether or not to participate in the labor force, with fixed hours of work.
In this setting, it can be optimal to adopt wage subsidies or inwork credits, with a negative
participation tax for lowincome households (see e.g., Christiansen, 2015; Choné & Laroque, 2005,
2011; Diamond, 1980; Jacquet, Lehmann, & Van der Linden, 2013; and Saez, 2002).
1
1
Jacquet et al. (2013) and Hansen (2018) consider a model with both intensive and extensive margin. Ndiaye (2018) also investigate a lifecycle model with an
intensive and extensive (endogenous retirement) margin.
Although these studies have provided influential findings, with both theoretical and policy
implications, a large part of the literature is static and does not directly address the
intertemporal side of the problem. A few studies employ dynamic models with an extensive
labor margin (see Laroque, 2011 and Choné & Laroque, 2017). They investigate an age
independent, nonlinear labor income tax/transfer in a stationary lifecycle model with a perfect
insurance market. Laroque (2011) analytically derives the properties of an optimal tax system
and shows that a worker faces a negative participation tax rate if the workers social weight with
respect to lifetime permanent income is larger than the average.
2
Under the stationary
assumption, the distributions of productivity and cost to work are constant over time, and the
correlation between current and permanent income becomes a central problem.
3
Because they
also assume a perfect insurance market, personal events, such as illness or accidents, are fully
insured by the private financial market. The main objective of the government in their model is
redistribution among households that have different permanent incomes at birth, which solely
determine their social weight. Therefore, Laroque (2011) and Choné and Laroque (2017) focus
analysis on an optimal ageindependent taxation. The main purpose of our study is to explore
both the qualitative and the quantitative properties of optimal agedependent, nonlinear labor
income tax, without a perfect insurance market.
Recent dynamic Mirrlees literature (see Kocherlakota, 2010) examines intertemporal shocks
on labor productivity and preferences mainly in the intensive labor margin. With regard to the
extensive margin, Diamond and Mirrlees (1978) and Golosov and Tsyvinski (2006) examine
permanent disability shocks. Here, once a worker is disabled, labor status is no longer a matter
of choice. In contrast, the shocks can be temporary and a household decides whether to
participate in the labor market in each period in our model. It is important to examine these
shocks because a household that decides not to work in a period for some reason (e.g., bad
health, involuntary unemployment, or lack of ability) may change its labor status and return to
work in another period.
The results from dynamic Mirrlees literature show that an optimal income tax policy with
shocks must be historydependent. The historydependent nature is, however, complicated and
rare in the real world. We focus solely on the role of agedependent income taxation to consider
a more relevant policy system, which rules out the possibility of implementing a full optimal
allocation.
4
As the seminal paper of Akerlof (1978) points out, some exogenously observable
characteristics are correlated with productivity or earnings. These taggingschemes reduce the
cost of income redistribution and enhance welfare. Age is one of the most relevant candidates
for this tagging scheme because it is easily observed by the government, and the average and the
variance of the income distribution could be correlated with age.
Several studies have analyzed agedependent income taxation. Using a static model,
Kremer (2002) shows that young workers should face lower marginal tax rates than older
workers do. In a dynamic homogeneous agent model, Erosa and Gervais (2002) and
Lozachmeur (2006) show an agedependent income taxation is optimal.
5
In a dynamic
2
Laroque (2011) also examines the usefulness of a complemental positive linear tax on wealth.
3
As noted in Laroque (2011), a perfect correlation between current and permanent income would make the static and the dynamic model equivalent.
4
Some papers consider labor income tax combined with other supplemental instruments to implement the optimal allocation. For example, Grochulski and
Kocherlakota (2010) show that the optimal allocation can be implemented through a combination of a tax on current labor income until retirement, a
retrospective capital income tax only at retirement that is dependent on labor income history, and a historycontingent payment after retirement. Michau (2014)
shows that the optimal allocation can be implemented by a historydependent social security system in a lifecycle model with both intensive and extensive
(retirement) margins and without skill shocks.
5
Lozachmeur (2006) incorporates education, the retirement age, and borrowing constraints in the lifecycle model.
KATAOKA AND TAKAMATSU
|
1339

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT