Open source—Is it an alternative to intellectual property?

AuthorNarendran Thiruthy
Date01 March 2017
Published date01 March 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jwip.12074
DOI: 10.1111/jwip.12074
NOTE
Open sourceIs it an alternative to intellectual
property?
Narendran Thiruthy
Inter University Centre for IPR Studies, Kochi,
Kerala, India
Correspondence
Narendran Thiruthy, Inter University Centre
for IPR Studies, Kochi, Kerala, India.
Email: narendranthiruthy@gmail.com
The open source production model is being articulated as an
alternative to the contemporary intellectual property model,
which uses property rights as instruments of exclusion and,
consequently, guarantees a market monopoly. The open source
movement initially originated as a creatorsresponse to the
extensive use of intellectual property law to protect the source
code of computer programs. Even though the movement began
modestly, open source has now become a practicing business
model. The efficiency of the open source production model in
coordinating collaborative creativity and in providing concrete
results is a proven fact in the software industry. The uniqueness of
this model lies in its facilitation of a distinctive use of property to
build an environment, that is more conducive to collaborative
production. Many theorists argue that open source has now
emerged as a workable alternative to current intellectual property
law, and that it resolves the many challenges intellectual property
law has posed in terms of access and creativity management. This
note attempts to explore the property jurisprudence and social
relationships in open source and critically examines how
successful the open source model is in emerging as an alternative
to intellectual property.
KEYWORDS
intellectual property rights jurisprudence, open source
software, property rights
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The idea of accelerating indu strial innovations by providing propert y rights as an incentive has demonstrated so me
positive results. Private prop erty rights act as exclusive rights from which their holders c an benefit and profit. As
exclusivity is fundamental to the concept of private prop erty, the intellectual prop erty right model allows its
owners to guard their innovati ons with enclosures. This cau ses issues in accessing, using an d improving such
© 2017 The Author. The Journal of World Intellectual Property © 2017 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
68
|
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jwip J World Intellect Prop. 2017;20:6886.
creations (Boldrin & Levine, 2008; Stallman, 2002). Some theorists argue that this exclusivity also causes an
unreasonable restraint on an individuals ability to use and enjoy such creations (Levy, 2001).
Open source is being articulated as an alternative to the intellectual property model to handle creativity. In open
source, a community of individuals makes contributions to a body of knowledge, sets up peer-review systems for
quality control and then nurtures and nourishes that body of knowledge (Benkler, 2002, p. 381). Open source works
through a unique licensing system that treats the creationas property and determines the way in which it can be
used and enjoyed. Open Source license creates a relationship between the creator and the user, which is distinct from
the way in which contemporary intellectual property right models are used to promote creativity. The distinction of
open source licensing is in its ability to use property as an institution to build an environment with lesser restrictions on
access and use. Some writers propagate the view that open sources goals are antithetical to intellectual property
ideals, and that the two are in continuous conflict
1
(Wayner, 2000).
In the intellectual property model, software development is linked with the existence of an owner who controls
the softwares production and use. Richard Stallman, who is a champion of the open source movement, criticizes the
intellectual property model by asserting that software should be free and that programmers should be motivated by
enhanced reputation and community good, rather than by remuneration or profit. Halbert (2003) opines that open
source is an alternative to the intellectual property model as it is based upon a set of fundamentally different
principles: First, the building blocks, that is, the source code, are available to everyone; second, any improvements
made by the user must be shared with the community of users; third, a business makes money not from the source
code, but from its product and support services; and finally, intellectual property rights are not a part of its business
model. She further says that instead of centralizing ownership in the hands of a few wealthy individuals, open source
decentralizes ownership and in the process, builds upon the creative energy of thousands. Other authors suggest that
the main difference between open source and proprietary software is in open sources focus on sharing and
cooperation, instead of control and exclusivity. They argue that open source licenses are an alternative to the
governance mechanisms in the intellectual property model (Valimaki, 2005, p. 113). Lindberg (2008) notes that in the
intellectual property model the proprietary software companies own the copyright to all of the software that
they distribute, while, alternatively, in the open source model projects are owned by their communities, or more
precisely by their contributors (p. 156). He explains that, just as depositors become part owners, when they put their
money into the credit union repository, coders become part owners when they put their code into the source code
repository (p. 156).
Another strong argument is that open source is an alternative to traditional economic intellectual property
incentives (Maher, 1999, p. 695). While contemporary intellectual property law is based on the assumption that only
economic incentives can motivate creators, open source contrasts that sentiment in every sense. Proponents of open
source argue that the open source model exposes the problems of proprietary systems and that the models
philosophy emphasizes the good of the community over the good of the individual (Halbert, 2003). The most
significant feature of open source is the voluntary contribution and sharing by creative people, just for the sake of the
information being used and enjoyed by others. The ongoing trend in contemporary literature is to praise this value
system and to advocate for its expansion into other realms of technology (Halbert, 2003). Open Source Chemistry,
Open Source Biotechnology and Open Source Drug Discovery are a few examplesof this trend. But as clarified earlier,
open source relies on the principles of intellectual property rights to create binding legal relationships among creators.
Thus, the property relationship, social organization and business dimensions of open source need to be analyzed to
determine how close open source is to emerging as an alternative to the present model of intellectual property.
1.1
|
The concept of property and its relationship to collaborative research
In modern times, a substantial proportion of technological innovation and a significant amount of artistic creation are
the result of collaborative research (Mandel, 2011, p. 2001). Present day research is characterized by large scale
collaborations owing to the need for multi-disciplinary expertise and the complexity of problems. Encouraging,
THIRUTHY
|
69

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT