On the Viability of Fixing Leaky Supply Chains for the Poor Through Benefit Transfers: A Call for Joint Distribution

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jbl.12189
Date01 June 2019
AuthorShashank Rao,Rahul Nilakantan,Kang Bok Lee,Deepak Iyengar
Published date01 June 2019
On the Viability of Fixing Leaky Supply Chains for the Poor
Through Benet Transfers: A Call for Joint Distribution
Shashank Rao
1
, Rahul Nilakantan
2
, Deepak Iyengar
3
, and Kang Bok Lee
1
1
Harbert College of Business, Auburn University
2
Indian Institute of Management Indore
3
Barney Barnett School of Business and Free Enterprise, Florida Southern College
Supply chain managers have yet to solve the conundrum of protably distributing and selling to the poorest consumers. Most prevailing
methods of addressing this problem take one of two contrasting approachesthat is, (1) price subsidization or (2) benets/cash transfers.
The former has been heavily studied in the literature with the consensus being that it is highly inefcient and prone to leaks. We investigate the
viability of the latter by focusing on how branching out to reach the poorest customers impacts the performance of banks. Results indicate that
the impacts of this approach are deleterious, thereby questioning its commercial scalability. Therefore, we argue that this approach may also
have only limited potential in terms of being an effective, large-scale solution to the problem of access for the poor. Instead, a third approach
to achieve scalable Bottom of the Pyramid growth and development needs to be consideredcultivating partnerships through joint distribution.
Keywords: transfer programs; branch network; sustainable growth; leaky supply chains; partnerships
INTRODUCTION
According to the World Bank, nearly half of the worlds popula-
tion lives in rural, underserved areas, and out of these, nearly
80% are poor. These populations constitute the so-called Bottom
of the Pyramid (BOP)a phrase describing that segment of the
population who lack access to basic goods and services. It has
been suggested that this group of people earn the equivalent of
just a few dollars a day (Banerjee and Duo 2007). In fact, the
rates of rural inequity in some countries are so dire that a com-
mon approach in the literature is to assume that entire rural pop-
ulations in some countries fall under this category (Whitney and
Kelkar 2004; Schwittay 2009; Zala and Patel 2009).
In several places, attempts have been made to improve the
quality of life of these populations. Often these initiatives
involve some form of joint publicprivate participation. The
guiding principle behind such programs for the private sector has
been that as value is created for these sections of the society,
organizations serving them will also nd value and thereby bene-
t from increased market penetration (London et al. 2010). This
in turn can lead to the twin goals of commercial protability and
social development while serving the BOP (Kuriyan et al. 2008).
While in a few cases, private enterprises have been able to do
this mostly on their own (Hart 2005), in a majority of instances,
some public-sector involvement has been critical (Varman et al.
2012).
One of the most common and time-tested approaches by
which the public sector gets involved in such initiatives is
through price subsidization (PS)trying to keep market prices of
certain goods and services in BOP markets low, in order to
increase their affordability to low-income buyers (Sodhi and
Tang 2016). In such cases, governmental involvement (and often,
government-controlled distribution systems) partially meets the
price of supplying the product to such markets, and the buyer is
left to pay a reduced share of the cost, thereby increasing afford-
ability, and by extension, demand. Therefore, this approach can
be considered a push-based distribution approach that focuses on
pushing cost-sheltered products through the distribution channel.
In addition, however, an alternative approach has now also
emerged. Often called direct benets/direct cash transfer (DBT),
it involves the subsidizing agency/government directly transfer-
ring cash to a recipient, who can then use it for designated pur-
poses (Rawlings and Rubio 2005; Bourguignon et al. 2008). In
contrast to the supply-side programs such as price subsidizing,
such programs try to grow the low-income market through de-
mand creation by providing purchasing power to poor consumers
(de Janvry and Sadoulet 2006). The immediate impact of such
programs is to capitalize on the income effectthat is, increased
nances available to the poorest consumers should increase con-
sumption spending, which in turn should prompt the private sec-
tor to nd this market attractive. Essentially, as private
companies realize that the previously poor now have purchasing
power, the belief is that they will deem it protable to sell to
them. Therefore, such programs represent a substantive change
in the approach to BOP development by moving from a pure
supply channel of subsidized products to a demand-based chan-
nel built around market mediation through a modication of the
consumersability to pay (e.g., Selen and Soliman 2002; De Tre-
ville et al. 2004).
While the DBT approach is intriguing and offers the promise
of a workable solution to an old problem, it is not completely
free of challenges either. One major concern has been that it cre-
ates increased dependence on a formal banking channel, given
the need for beneciaries to have bank accounts in order to
receive the transferred benets (Mundle 2016). This has
prompted regulatory or commercial environments wherein banks
are sometimes mandated to branch into underserved markets
(Besley 1995). While such mandates may have value from a
social standpoint, their commercial viability is subject to
Corresponding author:
Shashank Rao, Supply Chain Management and Information Systems,
Harbert College of Business, Lowder Hall, Auburn University,
Auburn, AL 36849, USA; E-mail: Shashank.rao@auburn.edu
Journal of Business Logistics, 2019, 40(2): 145160 doi: 10.1111/jbl.12189
© 2018 Council of Supply Chain Management Professionals
speculation. Unfortunately, extant research does not provide
much clarity at this point either. While some scholarship has
looked into the impact of a banks branching/geographic reach
on protability (e.g., Hirtle 2007; Hirtle and Stiroh 2007), this
work has largely been concentrated in developed markets and the
extent to which the same would translate into BOP markets is
unknown.
Our study seeks to address an issue fundamental to DBTs
large-scale rollout as a viable alternative to PS. We contend that if
DBT is to serve as a viable large-scale alternative to the supply
challenges presented by PS, banks need to be able to provide the
background infrastructure to make it happen. And yet they are
unlikely to want to do it unless they can do it protably. Therefore,
if bank branching at the BOP can be shown to be protable for
banks, then DBT can indeed serve as a viable solution to the sup-
ply chain and distribution challenges of PS. However, if this is not
the case, then other alternative approaches to this issue of BOP
access will need to be investigated, including opportunities for cost
reduction through joint distribution (Sodhi and Tang 2016) and
partnerships (Lambert 2014). Therefore, this article addresses the
commercial viability of a nancial-ow-based solution to a very
pressing supply challenge by answering the research question
How does increased geographic reach of banks through branching
in low-income markets impact their performance?
This article addresses the Special Topic Forums call by exam-
ining the viability of a unique theoretical framework in logistics
and supply chain management (LSCM) related to providing
products to the BOP. Indeed, it has been suggested that SCM
involves the overall management of three bidirectional ows
products/services, information, and nancial resources (Mentzer
et al. 2001). Yet a preponderance of scholarship in SCM
focusses on directly addressing the rst of these owsthat is,
products. This is especially true with respect to solutions for the
BOP, since most traditional approaches focus on distributing
goods to BOP consumers in a highly cost-sheltered/subsidized
manner and evaluating the commercial viability of the same
(e.g., Rangan et al. 2011; Mehta and Jha 2014). In contrast to
prior approaches, our focus is on the commercial viability of an
alternative solution for BOP development (i.e., nancial ow
management). Therefore, this article is positioned at the intersec-
tion of the disciplines of SCM and Financean emerging area
of interest for SCM scholars (e.g., Pfohl and Gomm 2009; Hof-
mann and Kotzab 2010; Sanders and Wagner 2011; Wuttke et al.
2013; Gelsomino et al. 2016).
LITERATURE REVIEW AND RESEARCH CONTEXT
Any initiative to turn the BOP into a viable marketplace has to
capitalize on the income effectan economic principle which
proposes that consumption patterns are enhanced by an increase
in a consumers real income and depressed by a reduction in it.
This real income change can come either by way of changing
the price that a customer pays for the goods (e.g., price subsi-
dization), or by changing the amount of money they have avail-
able. Traditional approaches (e.g., price control and
subsidization) have usually concentrated on the former, with lim-
ited long-term success. Because of this, the latter approach seems
to be gaining the interest of scholars and practitioners of late.
Price subsidization at the BOPsupply chain challenges
Even the initial writings that brought BOP into the mainstream
discourse acknowledged that the leading barrier to doing busi-
ness at the BOP was the complex physical distribution and
logistics required to get products to these places (Prahalad and
Hart 2002). Several factors contribute to this problemsmall
pack sizes, low margins, and lack of physical infrastructure to
house and distribute goods (Prahalad 2009; Karamchandani
et al. 2011; Sodhi and Tang 2016). In addition, because this
population is often geographically dispersed, the cost of serving
them is even higher than it would otherwise be (Karnani 2007;
London et al. 2011). Finally, given lack of purchasing power,
transactions in this segment represent too low an amount to
generate the scale economy needed for companies to build ef-
cient distribution systems (Karamchandani et al. 2011). All of
this means that direct entry into such low-income markets often
involves high setup/xed costs of establishing a brand new
supply chain, and it is therefore rather hard for companies to
do it protably. As a result, only a few major companies
attempt to navigate these headwinds and sell to this segment
(Schwittay et al. 2011; Simanis 2012; Kolk et al. 2014).
Instead, most companies that engage with the BOP in the
absence of external support tend to do so either as part of their
corporate social responsibility or charity programs (Simanis and
Milstein 2012; Fawcett and Waller 2015; Sodhi and Tang
2016).
One of the most common avenues by which such markets do
get access to goods and services typically involves some form of
governmental/public-sector involvement (Perez-Aleman and
Sandilands 2008). For example, Rangan et al. (2011) argue that
in the extreme-poverty segment, where delivering basic services
such as water, sanitation, health care, and education requires
heavy investments, companies have little choice but to enter into
publicprivate partnerships that provide guarantees on cost
recovery, subsidies, and market exclusivity(p. 117). Indeed, it
has been pointed out that a substantial portion of current BOP
initiatives exists because of such governmental or nonprot
involvement (Johnson 2007; Kolk et al. 2014).
Such initiatives are, however, often problematic because by
their very nature, a price differential is embedded into the phys-
ical delivery of the product. Given that goods are sold to the
BOP at a price that is below the open-market price, there is an
articial market distortion, which in turn provides opportunities
for arbitrage, supply-diversion, and proteering (Mundle 2016).
As a result, such large-scale programs are plagued with corrup-
tion and pilferagealso sometimes called leakages (Mehta and
Jha 2014; Chakrabarti et al. 2016). For example, in the Public
Distribution System of Indiathe worlds largest such subsi-
dized product distribution program for the poorit has been
estimated that nearly 42% of the products in the supply chain
are leaked and sold elsewhere at full price (Dreze and Khera
2015). Similarly, it has been argued that only about 60% of
subsidized fuel intended for BOP consumers in India reaches
the end-consumer, and the rest is leaked (Shenoy 2010), and in
the Philippines Rice Subsidy Program, it has been estimated
that nearly 48% of subsidized rice is leaked out of the distribu-
tion channel and sent to unintended recipients (Mehta and Jha
2014).
146 S. Rao et al.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT