On the value of Medicaid in providing access to long‐term care

AuthorMarkus Fels
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12380
Date01 August 2020
Published date01 August 2020
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:933948. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet © 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
|
933
Received: 2 July 2018
|
Accepted: 10 May 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12380
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
On the value of Medicaid in providing access to
longterm care
Markus Fels
Department of Economics, University of
Dortmund (TU), Dortmund, Germany
Correspondence
Markus Fels, University of Dortmund
(TU), Department of Economics,
Vogelpothsweg 87, 44227 Dortmund,
Germany.
Email: markus.fels@udo.edu
Abstract
The crowdingout by Medicaid has been identified as a
possible reason for the low demand for private long
term care (LTC) insurance in the USA. I extend the
previous analysis to the case in which budget constraints
inhibit access to care. This reduces the role of the
implicit tax and fundamentally changes the nature,
scope, and welfare implications of crowdingout. It
suggests a large value of Medicaid that a private
insurance market is unable to offer due to a dilemma
prevalent inbut not exclusive tothe market for LTC
insurance: a dilemma between access and affordability.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The state and development of the US market for longterm care (LTC) insurance has caused
worry among both researchers and policymakers. Despite the facts that the cost of LTC is
substantial, and that the risk of being in need of LTC is nonnegligible, the takeup of LTC
insurance is consistently low. Private insurance is responsible for as little as 46% of funding of
LTC. The main contributor is the public program of Medicaid that provides funding for the very
poor (Congressional Budget Office, 2004, 2013; Frank, 2012).
Several possible reasons for the low takeup of insurance, now termed the LTC insurance
puzzle, have been proposed and analyzed (Brown & Finkelstein, 2007, 2011; Cremer, Pestieau,
& Ponthière, 2013; Pestieau & Ponthière, 2010). A prime suspect has been found in the public
program of Medicaid crowdingout demand for private insurance (Brown & Finkelstein, 2008;
Brown, Coe, & Finkelstein, 2006; Pauly, 1989, 1990). In that line of argument, private insurance
simply duplicates Medicaid benefits thereby increasing the shadow price of insurance. The
effect, labeled as the implicit tax of Medicaid, is argued to be particularly strong for lowincome
groups, yet still relevant for those further up the income distribution. Brown and Finkelstein
A working paper version circulates under the title When the affordable has no value, and the valuable is unaffordable:
The U.S. market for longterm care insurance and the role of Medicaid.
(2008, 2011) argue that this crowdingout is welfaredecreasing as the public program itself
offers only very limited insurance value. In that way, Medicaid crowds out demand for a private
market that could offer a superior insurance value.
In this paper, I extend the analysis of Medicaid crowdout. The analysis so far assumes away the
risk of not being able to pay for LTC once in need. Yet, it is exactly this possibility that justifies the
existence of Medicaid. When the budget, that is available at the time when LTC is needed, is
uncertain ex ante, even a riskneutral individual sees a value both in Medicaid and in private
insurance as these enable access to care in those cases in which it is unaffordable out of onesown
resources.
1
However, as Medicaid ensures access to basic care, it denies private insurance to offer
such an access value. This changes the nature of crowdingout as it identifies the elimination of an
access value instead of the implicit tax as its most important component. The extent and importance
of the implicit tax in crowdingout is further reduced as most insurance plans require an insuree to
pay a sizable deductible before paying any benefits. The reception of insurance benefits is then
limited to the state in which the deductible is affordable. In the case that the deductible is not
affordable there simply do not exist insurance benefits that could duplicate Medicaid benefits.
Hence, there is no implicit tax. This issue is of particular relevance for the poor who have previously
been identified to face the maximal implicit tax. In strong contrast, I show that the implicit tax is
nonexistent for poor because they are unlikely to receive any insurance benefits as this requires a
deductible payment that is beyond their means. In addition, financial constraints may inhibit a
person to express his willingness to pay for an insurance plan, in which case actual demand reflects
ability to pay rather than willingness to pay. In this case, Medicaids impact on demand is reflected
in the explicit tax burden imposed by Medicaid, not by the implicit tax. Since the poor are most
restricted in their financial means, their demand response thus reflects their explicit tax burden
from Medicaid that, in a progressive taxation scheme, is low. Consequently, the analysis reveals that
the implicit tax is relevant for different people than previously identified.
2
This refutes the argument
that variations in the implicit tax can explain the observed variations of insurance ownership.
In addition to furthering the analysis of crowdingout by Medicaid, I seek to point out
alternative welfare implications. Concentrating on the value of insurance for consumption
smoothing, Brown and Finkelstein (2008, 2011) argue that Medicaid offers little value in this
regard and conclude that the crowdingout is decreasing welfare. To add to this analysis, I
conduct a welfare comparison based on the access value between public insurance via Medicaid
and private insurance via a competitive market. I show that, even under highly favorable
market conditions, private insurance markets are unable to provide the access value that a
government assistance program, such as Medicaid, can provide. This is due to a dilemma
unique to private insurance. To ensure access even for the very poor, an insurance policy cannot
prescribe a significant deductible. However, a sizable deductible is needed to make an insurance
policy affordable for most people, in particular the poor. In this way, private insurance can only
offer plans that are either not valuable or not affordable for people with low income. Public
insurance faces no such dilemma as it allows for the possibility of redistribution. The welfare
conclusions with regard to Medicaids impact are thus fundamentally opposed depending on
what is considered to be the primary purpose of Medicaid: offering consumptionsmoothing
opportunities or ensuring access.
1
Compare Nyman (1999) proposing an access motive in buying health insurance. See also Nyman (2003, p. 67 ff.).
2
While Nyman (2003, p. 122 ff.) already argues that replacing the access value of insurance is the major source of
crowdingout, he fails to recognize the detrimental effect of deductibles on insurance demand. The neglect of this effect
overstates the importance of demand crowdingout for the poor.
934
|
FELS

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT