On the Path to Trade Liberalisation: Political Regimes in Trade Negotiations

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12280
Published date01 July 2016
Date01 July 2016
On the Path to Trade Liberalisation:
Political Regimes in Trade Negotiations
Florian M
olders
International Finance Corporation, Washington, DC, USA
1. INTRODUCTION
DESPITE the World Trade Organization’s (WTO) effort to promote multilateral trade lib-
eralisation, there has been a surge in bilateral and multilateral free trade agreements
(FTAs) instead. Consequently, the proliferation of these agreements encouraged the WTO to
frame FTAs in terms of coherence instead of co-existence (WTO, 2011). While we have an
idea of what sort of countries eventually enter into trade agreements (see Mansfield et al.,
2002; Baier and Bergstrand, 2004; Martin et al., 2012), there is little known about what deter-
mines the duration prior to actual enforcement.
1
This is particularly important if the expecta-
tions of forward-looking firms (exporters) rely on credible information on the date of tariff
removal to initiate investment and exporting operations. In 2010, when the Nobel Prize was
awarded to Liu Xiaobo, China postponed trade talks on the bilateral ChinaNorway FTA (The
Guardian, 2010). This is an indication of the sensitivity of trade negotiations to the types of
political regimes and forms a central part of this paper.
Durations from the start of the negotiations through enforcement differ considerably:
ranging from just under one year in the case of the Pan-Arab Free Trade Area to over
10 years for the bilateral trade initiative between Panama and Chile. Yet, the literature has
so far missed out on the dynamics that go hand in hand with trade policy; specifically,
the anticipation of trade liberalisation offers an abundance of research questions. Burstein
and Melitz (2011) analyse transition dynamics at the firm level in the course of trade lib-
eralisation by focusing on innovation activities that determine the decision to export and
the trade volume prior trade liberalisation. In a similar vein, Bergin and Lin (2012) empir-
ically show that trade increments are triggered well ahead of the enforcement of the Euro-
pean Monetary Union (EMU). In both papers, the authors refer to firm behaviour as the
leading driver to a trade increases, mainly triggered by a shift in expectations with respect
to future profits in the foreign market. In this context, policy uncertainty is an issue in the
international economics literature that deserves further attention as it adds a new perspec-
tive to the interaction between the private sector and the policy level. Handley and Lim~
ao
(2012) contribute to this debate by assessing Portugal’s accession to the European Union
The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the
IFC, IFC management or the World Bank Group. All errors and omissions are sole responsibility of the
author.
1
The enforcement of a trade agreement in this study refers to the end of the ratification process,
whereas implementation is not necessarily to coincide with an agreement in force (entry into force is a
necessary but insufficient condition for implementation). The end point of the ratification stage is defined
as the legal enforcement of the agreement in all participating countries.
©2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
890
The World Economy (2016)
doi: 10.1111/twec.12280
The World Economy
(EU). Even though trade barriers were lifted well ahead of the formal accession to the
EU, trade-creating effects only emerged after Portugal officially joined the bloc.
2
Economic actors adjust their expectations according to new information. Forward-looking
firms react to news on countries willing to form a trade agreement as this directly impacts
their cost function. However, little is known about what country characteristics shape the pro-
cess towards an agreements’ enforcement. The contribution of this paper is therefore twofold:
(i) it focuses on duration rather than just successful conclusion of agreements and (ii) distin-
guishes the two phases of cooperation, negotiation and ratification, with a focus on driving
factors from the political spectrum. The results allow a better evaluation of the announc e-
ments of trade initiatives and thereby may help to reduce uncertainty involved in the interac-
tion between firms and policymakers. Using a data set with time-varying covariates, the
determinants of the duration of FTA negotiations are found to be multidimensional. Political
aspects, especially the levels of democratisation and political constraints, matter.
3
Controlling for various influences on the negotiation and ratification durations, my findings
suggest that bilateral trade agreements (BTA) reflect significant faster negotiation processes as
compared to agreements with more than two countries involved. The same effect on the nego-
tiation process is observed for countries that are more reliant on international trade. I find sup-
port for the claim that political regime types play a major role in determining the duration of
the pre-enforcement process: delays during the negotiation phase are more likely if countries
have less democratic political systems. This is measured through a composite polity index
(Polity2) and other indicators that provide information on the levels of democracy and politi-
cal constraints. The increasing application of additional trade provisions is taken into accou nt
by including the number of WTO-X and WTO+provisions that mirror the depth of a trade
agreement. It is found that these provisions are associated with significant increases in the
duration of negotiations and ratifications. The implications for trade policy from this research
are manifold: first, if the fast finalisation of trade negotiations with a single country is a prior-
ity, countries should seek a bilateral agreement instead of a multilateral one. Second, political
constraints (which often go hand in hand with a country’s democratisation) come at a cost:
they are associated with longer negotiation periods.
4
Third, the pre-enforcement process of
deeper agreements needs more time. Reductions in non-tariff barriers often intervene with
national policies and policymakers may therefore be more sensitive regarding changes in the
respective sectors.
5
The paper is structured as follows: the next section reviews the respective literature on
international trade and cooperation, while Section 3 outlines the determinants of interest in
this study for the duration of negotiation and ratification stages. The data and the econometric
specifications are described in Sections 4 and 5, respectively. Section 6 presents the results on
the duration of the negotiation and ratification processes before Section 7 concludes.
2
Handley and Lim~
ao (2012) interpret this as a sign of revealed uncertainty in the private sector as firms
had to take into account a potential policy reversal.
3
I refer to all types of trade agreements as FTAs, including customs unions and preferential trade agree-
ments. In the regression analysis of Section 6, the results only change marginally in the magnitude of
the coefficients, if customs unions, for example, are excluded.
4
Yet, there is supportive evidence that more time spent on negotiating is associated with faster ratifica-
tions.
5
See also an article by Economist (2013) which reports on the potential free-trade deal between the
USA and EU. Accordingly, it argues that ‘[e]asy deals [reductions in tariff levels] have mostly been
done; what is left is complicated’.
©2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
POLITICAL REGIMES IN TRADE NEGOTIATIONS 891
2. RELATED LITERATURE
In the following, I review the literature on (i) anticipatory trade effects and (ii) timing
and duration of investment and trade policies. The former relates to the empirical analysis
in this paper as it bridges the outcome of the analysis (what factors are associated with
the duration of trade negotiations and ratifications?) with the implications this might have
for private sector companies assessing the timing until trade barrier removal. Exporting
firms, for example, invest and trade in anticipation of trade and investment policies, based
on information on the timing of the enforcement of these policies. The second part of this
review then discusses papers directly related to duration models applied to trade and
investment policies.
a. Anticipatory Trade Effects
The results of the majority of papers on the trade-creating effects of FTAs lead to the
conclusion that trade is triggered by the implementation of an agreement (examples
include Frankel, 1997: Glick and Rose, 2002). While the literature on the ex post trade
effects of FTAs is exhaustive, there is substantial room for contributions that aim at inves-
tigating the accompanying effects of trade agreements. In this section, I first give a brief
overview on the discussion about anticipatory trade effects of FTAs before I summarise
the relevant body of literature that deals with duration analysis in the context of
international treaties.
Since Freund and McLaren (1999) pointed out anticipatory effects of trade agreements,
the notion of pre-implementation effects has been included in successive analyses. Accord-
ing to their results, trade adjustment led to anticipatory trade effects four years before
countries officially joined the EU. Other contributions to the literature seem to affirm the
presence of anticipatory trade effects of trade agreements. Results by Magee (2008) show
that there is substantial anticipation prior to an agreement’s implementation, if controlled
for leads in a gravity model analysis. In a similar vein, M
olders and Volz (2011) analyse
pre-enforcement effects from a different angle by focusing on the consecutive stages of
enforcement that an FTA runs through. Their results point towards the existence of
anticipatory trade effects in the context of East Asian bilateral FTAs during the negotia-
tion stage of an FTA. Handley and Lim~
ao (2012) examine Portugal’s accession to the
EU. Prior to its formal inclusion into the trade bloc, trade preferences were already at the
free-trade level for industrial goods. However, there was a substantial increase in trade
flows after the accession was formally concluded. This stresses the importance of formal
trade agreements for increasing credibility and exploiting the full scope of the trade
potential.
With respect to the impact of regime types on cooperation, Mansfield et al. (2002) find that
states which are classified as being more democratic have a good chance of successfully con-
cluding FTAs. In a similar vein, Mansfield and Milner (2012) re-emphasise this claim, but
focus on the role of veto players in the ratification period of a trade agreement. When policy-
makers have to decide on whether to form an FTA, they compare the potential benefits (e.g.
better economic performance via free trade) against the costs arising during the negotiation
and ratification stages. Democratic countries are more likely to form an agreement,
although the associated political constraints increase the costs (decrease the likelihood) of the
respective ratification.
©2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
892 F. M
OLDERS

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT