Oil “Rents” and Political Development: What Do We Really Know About the Curse of Natural Resources?

AuthorSarah M. Brooks,Marcus J. Kurtz
Published date01 September 2022
Date01 September 2022
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/00104140211060281
Subject MatterArticles
Article
Comparative Political Studies
2022, Vol. 55(10) 16981731
© The Author(s) 2022
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/00104140211060281
journals.sagepub.com/home/cps
Oil Rentsand Political
Development: What Do
We Really Know About
the Curse of Natural
Resources?
Sarah M. Brooks
1
and Marcus J. Kurtz
1
Abstract
Research on the political implications of oil wealth is now over two decades
old, and yet still unresolved. Despite many advances in this literature, a core
conceptresource rentsremains under-theorized, and even less well
measured. This mis-measurement, we contend, has direct and signif‌icant
consequences for theoretical f‌indings on the resource curse. Although rents
refer to excessive prof‌its, analyses to date have not directly or indirectly
focused on the prof‌itability of oil extraction; instead they rely more often on
estimates of gross receipts or exports of natural resources. The largely
untested assumption that oil sales consistently produce enormous prof‌its has
been the bridge used to treat these as measures of rents, even as the empirical
foundations for this claim are shaky. In contrast, we measure the diff‌iculty of
oil production using data from over 3800 major oil f‌ields around the globe
between 1980 and 2012 to more accurately estimate the income generated by
oil production and to calibrate its rent-generating potential using important
correlates of its cost of production. The results show that where oils cost of
production is low, and its prof‌itability high, pernicious regime outcomes are
observed in keeping with resource curse claims. However, as production
shifts to more challenging sources, oil production loses this association and
1
Ohio State University, Columbus, OH, USA
Corresponding Author:
Marcus J. Kurtz, Department of Political Science, Ohio State University, 154 N. Oval Mall, 2140
Derby Hall, Columbus, OH 43210-1373, USA.
Email: kurtz.61@osu.edu
may well at the extremes be associated with modestly more democratic
outcomes. In other words, it is only easy oilthat may be a curse for
democratic development.
Keywords
resource curse, democracy, political development, oil
Introduction
More than a quarter century after Sachs and Warners seminal research
launched a discussion about the relationship between natural resource en-
dowments and slow economic growth (Sachs and Warner, 1995,1999) a rich
literature in political economy has emerged examining the resource cursein
democratic development. Since that time, scholars have linked substantial
natural resource wealth to myriad domestic political ills, from corruption and
administrative bloat, to civil conf‌lict, pervasive clientelism, and the persis-
tence of authoritarianism (e.g., Collier & Hoeff‌ler, 1998;Dixit, 2007;Ross,
1999,2001,2013;Sokoloff & Engerman, 2000;Torvik, 2001,2002).
1
This
has been especially the case for one particular (and particularly important)
natural resource: oil. And it takes only a brief glance at the political char-
acteristics of the petro-states of the Middle East and Central Asia for the prima
facie linkage between oil and authoritarianism to become apparent.
At the same time, cracks have begun to emerge in the once-regnant
consensus linking oil to pernicious and authoritarian politics. Indeed, a re-
cent wave of resource curse scholarship has suggested that the negative effects
of oil wealth are instead conditionalon public versus private ownership
(Luong & Weinthal, 2010), pre-existing levels of administrative capacity
(Karl, 1997), human capital (J. P. C. Stijns, 2005,2006), institutional quality
(Bulte et al., 2005;Mehlum et al., 2006;Robinson et al., 2006;Snyder, 2006;
Torvik, 2009), local context (Brollo et al., 2013;Diaz-Rioseco, 2016;
Dunning, 2008;Gervasoni, 2010;Goldberg et al., 2008;Orihuela, 2018), and
international context (Hendrix, 2018). Others have suggested that while
natural resource wealth does not directly induce authoritarian political de-
velopment, natural resources instead stabilize whatever the incumbent regime
type might be (Morrison, 2009;Smith, 2007,2017;Ulfelder, 2007)which
tends to be authoritarian in much of the developing world. In a study of the
long-term linkages between oil wealth and political regime, moreover, Haber
and Menaldo (2011) do not detect a clear association (either positive or
negative) between oil wealth and democracy when the statistical analysis is
properly specif‌ied to emphasize within-country dynamics.
2
Brooks and Kurtz 1699
After many years of serious scholarship, therefore, research on the re-
source curseis perhaps further from a consensus on the political effects of
natural resource wealth than it was a decade or more ago. This dissensus
should not surprise us, however, if we consider that few existing treatments of
the political resource curse have converged on a set of concepts and measures
that would enable scholars to put the theory and its proposed mechanisms to a
clear empirical test. Scholars disagree, for example, about whether the curse
of natural resourcesis def‌ined by their abundance, or by the countrys
dependence(on resource exports), or by the amount of income accruing
from the sale of those resources. And, the measures have not always matched
the concept at issue very directly. Critical here is the concept of rents.Most
strains of research have argued that certain types of natural resource
productionparticularly that of oilproduce economic windfallsthat are
easily captured by governments (Rosser, 2006). And it is primarily from such
allegedly easy money that malign political outcomes derive, including,
conf‌lict, corruption, clientelism, malgovernance, or authoritarian persistence
(Boschini et al., 2007;Greene, 2010;Paler, 2013;Ross, 2013;Snyder, 2006;
Snyder & Bhavnani, 2005).
There are, however, both theoretical and empirical questions about the way
in which this basic claim has been treated in the literature. For instance, most
scholarship takes as an assumption that oil extraction produces rents for
producers, and that such rents are easily appropriated by the state in large
quantities (either through direct ownership or taxation of private oil-producing
f‌irms). This income is generally labeled as non-taxrevenue, to distinguish it
from the harder-to-getresources extracted through direct and indirect
taxation.
3
A critical challenge, however, is that this empirical work has not generally
measured the oil rentsthat are at the core of the resource curse theory and
analysis. This is problematic insofar as rentsreturns to a productive factor in
excess of its next best utilizationare the critical piece of most resource curse
causal mechanisms. Without large volumes of easy moneyaccruing to the
state, few if any of the presumed political consequences of oil endowment
should actually be expected.
4
Instead of measuring the actual prof‌its produced by oil (or other natural
resources), scholars have instead relied on a variety of output, export, and
receipts indicators. For instance, much of the foundational work on resource-
induced problems focused on the gross value of resource exports (typically as
a share of GDP). But this measurement strategy raises two challenges: f‌irst, it
counts only exported oil as revenue producing, and second, it assumes that oil
is costless to produce (or, at least equally costly to produce everywhere if one
takes the measure to be a correlate of the rents produced). More recent work
has improved on these assumptions, however, relying on the sale value of oil
productionnormed to GDP or population, but still requiring the assumption
1700 Comparative Political Studies 55(10)

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT