Oil price volatility and real options: 35 years of evidence

Published date01 December 2019
AuthorJohn Elder
Date01 December 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/fut.22057
J Futures Markets. 2019;39:15491564. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/fut © 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
|
1549
Received: 28 December 2018
|
Accepted: 26 August 2019
DOI: 10.1002/fut.22057
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Oil price volatility and real options: 35 years of evidence
John Elder
Department of Finance and Real Estate,
Colorado State University, Fort Collins,
Colorado
Correspondence
John Elder, Department of Finance and
Real Estate, Colorado State University,
Fort Collins, CO 805281272.
Email: john.elder@colostate.edu
Abstract
There has been a surge in interest in the effects of uncertainty on investment
decisions, motivated at least in part by the theory of real options. For example,
Bloom (2009, Econometrica,77, 623685) shows that higher uncertainty causes
firms to temporarily pause investment and hiring, generating sharp economic
downturns. This paper investigates these effects by examining the response of
disaggregated measures of production to volatility in oil prices. We find that
increased oil price volatility has strong negative effects on the production of
durable goods, such as transportation equipment, and oil exploration, such as
the drilling of oil and gas wells.
KEYWORDS
oil volatility, real options, uncertainty
JEL CLASSIFICATION
E32; G17; G31
1
|
INTRODUCTION
There has been a resurgence of interest in the effects of uncertainty on economic activity. Bloom (2009), in a general
equilibrium model, shows that higher uncertainty causes firms to temporarily pause investment and hiring,
contributing to sharp but brief economic downturns. He finds empirical support for this model with aggregate measures
of uncertainty. Bloom, Bond, and Van Reenen (2007) find that aggregate uncertainty, such as the 1973 oil crisis, reduces
the responsiveness of investment to demand shocks. Bansal and Yaron (2004) show that uncertainty risk may increase
precautionary savings and decrease consumption. Panousi and Papanikolaou (2012) find that high uncertainty tends to
be associated with lower investment in a panel of firms. Baker, Bloom, and Davis (2016) show that uncertainty about
economic policy tends to precede declines in investment and output. Wang, Xu, and Zhong (2018) examine the effect of
economic policy uncertainty on CDS spreads.
An important channel for the effects of uncertainty is the theory of real options. This theory suggests that an increase
in uncertainty about the return to an underlying asset tends to increase the time value of a call option on that asset,
delaying exercise. Uncertainty may then diminish the willingness of individual firms to commit resources to irreversible
investments and, similarly, the willingness of consumers to commit resources on relatively illiquid durables. This was
shown for financial options by Black and Scholes (1973), and popularized in capital budgeting by Dixit and Pindyck
(1994) and others. Giaccotto, Gerson, and Shantaram (2007) analyze real options in the context of a durable good.
The empirical evidence highlighting the importance of uncertainty for aggregate production and investment
decisions is abundant, but empirical evidence at the industry and firmlevel is less so. Moel and Tufano (2002) examine
the behavior of Brazilian mine closings. Grullon, Lyandres, and Zhdanov (2012) examine the implication of real options
for firmlevel returns and volatility. Kellogg (2014) finds oil price volatility causes drilling activity in Texas to decline.
Ritz and Walther (2015) examine the response of banks to funding uncertainty. Carvalho (2018) analyzes the effects of
political uncertainty in Brazil on manufacturing firms.
We extend this literature by using relatively granular and comprehensive industrylevel production data to explore
the theoretical predictions from the real options literature. In particular, we examine the effect of uncertainty on the
subindices of industrial production (IP), as compiled by the Federal Reserve Board of Governors. The broad index
measures domestic industrial output, which accounts for about onefifth of U.S. gross domestic product. The subindices
measure production at the two, three, four and five digit North American Industry Classification System (NAICS), as
published by the U.S. Office of Management and Budget. At the threedigit level, IP is attributed to more than two
dozen industries. As an example of the granularity provided by this data, transportation equipment (NAICS 336)
provides separate categories for the production of motor vehicles (NAICS 3361), which is divided into automobile and
lightduty motor vehicle (33611) and heavyduty trucks (33612), which are distinguished from motor vehicle body and
trailer (3362), motor vehicle parts (3363), and other subindices. This permits a focused empirical analysis with the
opportunity to investigate theoretical implications that are not possible with more aggregated data.
1
We use a statistical measure of uncertainty based on oil prices, as in Bredin, Elder, and Fountas (2011). Alternative
measures of uncertainty include survey data (Bachmann, Elstner, & Sims, 2013) and newspaper citations (Baker et al.,
2016). Measuring uncertainty from commodity prices has some advantages. They are easily quantifiable, marketbased,
and there exists considerable evidence that oil prices have strong real effects, at least since Hamilton (1983). They are
also closely related to other measures of uncertainty, as Bloom (2009) shows that measures of uncertainty based on
newspaper citations are linked to measures based on commodity prices.
Importantly, our empirical model permits oil price volatility to affect production independently of the relation between oil
prices and production. For example, lower oil prices may tend to increase manufacturing production, while greater oil price
volatility may tend to simultaneously dampen manufacturing production. Our model also accommodates production activity
related to oil exploration, such as the drilling of oil and gas wells. In these industries, we would expect lower oil prices to be
associated with less drilling, while greater oil price volatility would tend to reinforce this decline.
Other authors who have examined the role of oil prices in uncertainty and risk include Pindyck (2004), Kellogg
(2014), and Chiang, Hsuan, Hughen, and Sagi (2015). Gao, Hitzemann, Shaliastovich, and Xu (2018) develop a model
that details a mechanism by which firms choose not to invest during periods of high oil price volatility. P2012m develop
a real business cycle model incorporating oil price volatility, finding that oil price volatility produces a temporary
decrease in durables. Elder and Serletis (2010) find that volatility in oil prices has tended to depress some components
of quarterly aggregate investment and durables consumption.
Our empirical results are strong. We find that oil price volatility tends to depress durables production at the two,
three, four, and five digit NAICS industry levels. The decline in output is particularly large for industries that are highly
dependent on energy prices, such as the production of transportation equipment. We also find that oil price volatility
has a negative and significant effect on oil and gas exploration, including the drilling of wells. The magnitude of the
effect we estimate is broadly consistent with predictions from theory, such as Bloom (2009). In particular, we estimate
that a volatility shock at the 90th percentile reduces durables production by about 2.3 percentage points at an annual
rate. The effects in some sectors, such as transportation, is even larger. Our results are robust to changes in the
empirical specification, including different sample periods and different measures of oil volatility, such as stochastic
volatility and implied volatility from option prices.
2
|
EMPIRICAL MODEL
Our empirical model is based on Bredin et al. (2011) and Elder (2004), and is briefly summarized here. The model is
structural vector autoregression, generalized to permit the structural disturbances to be conditionally heteroskedastic
and to permit the conditional variance to interact with the conditional mean
tBy C ΓyΓyΓyH ε= + + + ··· + + Λ() + ,
ttt ptp t1–1 2–2 1/2
(1)
where dim(B) = dim(Γ
i
) = (N × N), ε
t
ψ
t1
~iid N(0,H
t
), H
t
is diagonal, and ψ
t1
denotes the information set at time
t1, which includes variables dated t1 and earlier.
1
Guo and Kliesen (2005) is an insightful early paper that examines the effects of oil volatility on aggregated IP. Kliesen (2008), Rentschler (2013) andPinno and Serletis (2013) also examine the effects
of oil volatility, although they examine a small subset of the production measures considered here with different empirical models. For example, these papers do not include more granular data on
motor vehicles and the drilling of oil and gas wells.
1550
|
ELDER

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT