Oil nationalisations as protracted affairs: evidence from Venezuela

Date01 March 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/opec.12061
AuthorJorge E Portillo
Published date01 March 2016
Oil nationalisations as protracted affairs:
evidence from Venezuela
Jorge E Portillo
Deputy Manager, Department of Economic Research, Central Bank of Venezuela, Caracas 1010,
Venezuela. Email: jportill@bcv.org.ve
Abstract
Empirical studies tend to treat oil nationalisations as basically discrete, sudden events, an approach
that in some cases might be misleading and adds little to disentangle causality. On a contrary vein,
we take a closer look at the 1970s nationalisation of Venezuela’s oil industry and find evidence that
this was a rather protracted affair,expanding over a 17-year period. Weargue that although the trans-
fer of all assets to government hands was not completed until 1975, oil companies fullyanticipated
such move as early as 1958 and started to operate in a way compatible with a much shorter time
horizon. Specifically,we use an estimate of the resource rent (defined as output price minus marginal
extraction cost) to show a major shift in oil firms’ implicit time horizon after 1958. Our results help
to explain the rather weak causality link found in the data between oil nationalisations and price
fluctuations.
1. Introduction
Starting in the late-1990s, there has been a fresh wave of forced nationalisations of major
oil assets around the world, which in turn has rekindled the academic interest on the
subject.1A common feature in all these studies is the use of a rather static analytical frame-
work, where nationalisations are basically one-sided, discrete events: Every period, the
host government weighs its options so that when the gains of nationalising outweigh the
costs, then oil assets are seized; otherwise, it is business as usual.As a case in point, Guriev
et al. (2011) argue that, in line with the relational contracts literature, there is an inefficient
equilibrium where, in response to a positive oil price shock, governmentswill nationalise
oil assets rather than impose higher taxes.They use panel data on nationalisations in the oil
industry around the world during 1960–2006 to estimate conditional logit and probit
models with country fixed effects and find that governments are more likelyto nationalise
when oil prices are high (relative to the long-term trend) and when ‘political institutions
are weak’, in the sense that the government cannot crediblycommit itself not to national-
ise. On a contrary vein, Kennedy and Tiede (2011) find little qualitative and quantitative
evidence to support a causal connection between high oil prices and nationalisations and
©2016 Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries. Published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd, 9600 Garsington
Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.
50
instead they suggest that ‘politics drive nationalizations’. Specifically, they use the same
dataset as Guriev et al. (2011) to estimate a logit model where the eventof nationalisation
is a function of various proxies for political conditions, finding empirical support for three
main political drivers of oil nationalisations: first, the relative importance of the oil sector
in the overall economy, in the sense that the pursuit of a nationalistic agenda and broader
development goals increase the political rational for control of strategic sectors; second,
the role of policy diffusion, as political entrepreneurs reduce over time the information
problem of would-be nationalisers; and third, the duration of the political regime, in the
sense that younger political regimes are more likely to nationalise as a way to dilute any
political alliance between the international oil companies and the old political elites.
In this context, we take a closer look at the 1970s nationalisation of Venezuela’s oil
industry and find evidence that this was a rather protracted affair,expanding over a 17-year
period, so that reducing such complex dynamics into a single date (when the handover of
assets finally took place) is misleading and adds little to disentangle causality. In that
sense, our research lends support to Kennedy and Tiede’s methodological stand which
favours causal process observation. Specifically, we argue that although the transfer of all
oil assets to government hands was not completed until 1975, the international oil compa-
nies anticipated such move as earlyas 1958 (when an executive order brought to a halt the
leasing of new fields for the exploration) and started to operate in a waycompatible with a
much shorter time horizon.
Our main hypothesis is that international oil companies perceived the 1958 shift in
leasing policies not as a mere threat of nationalisation by the Venezuelan government,
but rather as an ‘early notification’ and adjusted their time horizon accordingly.A similar
claim is advanced by Cakir-Melek (2014) who uses data on the Venezuelan oil industry
to calibrate a dynamic model of a representative foreign firm and simulate the response
to 1961 ‘news’ that a nationalisation was expected to materialise by 1970. The model
predicts that foreign firms would increase extraction effort and reduce exploratory
efforts in anticipation of nationalisation, although no indication is given as to how firms
came about such ‘news’ and the adjustment predicted bythe model is slower than what is
actually observed in the data. In any case, this is only a calibration exercise and does not
provide econometric evidence about the shift in the firm’s time horizon, which is the
focus of the present study.
Westart by pointing out that if an exhaustible resource is to be optimally extracted, the
value of the remaining stock of resource has to be zero at the end of the last year of opera-
tion. This can be achievedby either depleting all the stock available or by driving down to
zero the resource rent (defined as output price minus marginal extraction cost) as the firm
approaches the time horizon. In fact, in the presence of a declining output price, it might be
necessary to increase production over time in order to raise the marginal extraction cost
fast enough to drive the resource rent towardzero, which is actually what happened during
©2016 Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries OPEC Energy Review March 2016
Oil nationalisations as protracted affairs 51

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT