Oil jump risk

Published date01 August 2020
Date01 August 2020
AuthorCraig Pirrong,Nima Ebrahimi
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/fut.22129
J Futures Markets. 2020;40:12821311.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/fut1282
|
© 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC
Received: 17 December 2019
|
Accepted: 1 May 2020
DOI: 10.1002/fut.22129
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Oil jump risk
Nima Ebrahimi
1
|Craig Pirrong
2
1
Department of Finance, Tulane
University, New Orleans, Louisiana
2
Department of Finance, University of
Houston, Houston, Texas
Correspondence
Nima Ebrahimi, Tulane University,
Goldring Woldenberg Hall I, 7 McAlister
Drive, New Orleans, LA 70118.
Email: nebrahimi@tulane.edu
Abstract
The risk premium associated with large upside jumps in oil market is a significant
driver of the crosssection of stock returns from 1986 to 2014. In contrast to
previous research, variance risk is priced only when we do not control for jumps.
Upward jumps are priced in tight supplydemand conditions but not in more
abundant supply periods. There is some evidence that downward jumps are priced
in abundant supply conditions but not in tight conditions. Innovations in risk
neutral jumps have predictive power for important economic indicators, including
notably consumption growth. This helps explain the pricing of jump risks.
KEYWORDS
crosssection of stock returns, downside jump risk premium, portfolio selection, upside jump risk
premium, variance risk premium
1|INTRODUCTION
Large oil price spikes and drops have been the subject of a substantial amount of research in finance and economics during
the recent decades. More recently, scholars have examined the effect of time variation in oil price volatility on asset prices.
Ebrahimi and Pirrong (2018) have extended this study to quantify the effects of time variation in higher moments (skewness
and kurtosis) on asset prices. In this article, we extend further that inquiry by investigating how upward and downward
jumps, which drive skewness and kurtosis, affect asset returns, and whether these factors have predictive power over real
variables (e.g., gross domestic product [GDP] growth) and measures of oil market fundamentals.
The main motivation is that our previous research shows that in a competition among variance, skewness, and
kurtosis, variance loses its significance in explaining crosssection of stock returns after controlling for skewness and
kurtosis. In addition, we find that the kurtosis effect explains more of the the crosssection of stock returns and retains
its significance through different subperiods and different option maturities. Since upside and downside jumps in oil
prices can affect skewness and kurtosis, in this article we attempt to provide a deeper understanding of what drives the
explanatory power of higher oil return moments for the crosssection of stock returns.
There are several reasons why we are focusing on oil market in this paper. A series of articles stretching back
decades have shown that oil price shocks have macroeconomic effects, and affect stock returns (Engemann, Kliesen, &
Owyang, 2011; Hamilton, 1996,2003,1983; Kilian, 2009; Kilian & Park, 2009; Kilian & Vigfusson, 2017,2013).
Moreover, options on crude oil futures are highly liquid, and therefore, we can use them to construct reliable
estimates of different measures of oil price risk. Among commodities, crude oil derivatives are the most liquid. In
particular, it is possible to use option prices from this liquid market to calculate implied variances, and estimates of the
(risk neutral) probabilities of downward and upward jumps. It is also possible to use options portfolios that are hedged
against certain risks to estimate how each of these factors is priced by investors. For example, the returns on an oil
futures option portfolio that is hedged against variance risk measures the premium that investors demand to bear the
upside and downside jumps.
The connection between oil market conditions, oil prices, and macroeconomic activity suggests that measures of oil
price risk, and investor preferences regarding these risks, may have some power to predict oil market fundamentals and
macroeconomic activity (Gao, Hitzemann, Shaliastovich, & Xu, 2016). Furthermore, this connection between oil market
conditions and economic activity, and the connection between economic activity and equity risk premia, suggests that
oil price risk measures may be priced factors: therefore, we also explore whether oil risk premia affect the crosssection
of equity returns (Christoffersen & Pan, 2017; Feuno et al., 2017).
Identifying the causal relationship between oil prices and macroeconomic variables is challenging. As discussed by
Alquist, Kilian, and Vigfusson (2013), the real price of oil has been endogenous to the world's economic condition since 1974:
the economic conditions of the oilimporting countries have a direct effect on the real price of oil and vice versa. This is what
makes it very hard to identify the causal relationship between the oil price and macroeconomic conditions in industrialized,
oilimporting economies. Furthermore, as proposed by Hamilton (2003), if we suppose that the major oil price fluctuations
are the result of the disruptions in oil production which is mainly caused by exogenous geopolitical tensions in the Middle
East such as the 1973 Yom Kippur War, the 19731974 oil embargo, Iranian Revolution of 1979, and the Persian Gulf War of
19901991, we can identify the impact of oil price shocks on macroeconomic activity. However, as pointed out by different
papers (e.g., Kilian, 2014) there is some evidence that demand shocks arising from the macroeconomy impact oil prices:
Barsky and Kilian (2001). This twoway causation makes identification challenging.
An approach to the endogeneity problem is to use option prices to disentangle the supply and demand effects and to
use the exogenous supplydriven component to see if it can predict the macroeconomic variables and explain the cross
sectional variation of stock returns. Specifically, the prices of relatively short maturity (e.g., 60 days), deep outofthe
money call options can be used to measure of the probability of large upward jumps in oil prices. Such large jumps are
most likely to be caused by exogenous supply shocks like those emphasized by Hamilton. Conversely, deep outofthe
money puts measure the likelihood of large downward jumps in prices. Such jumps are sometimes caused by severe
economic contraction, and hence downward jumps are a potential proxy for demandside shocks (e.g., the Asian Crisis
of 1998, or the Financial Crisis of 20082009); since large price declines can also be the result of supply shocks (e.g., the
Saudi increase in output in 1986, or 2014, or the Shale Revolution), however, the identification of downward jumps with
demand shocks and is not as clearcut as the identification of upward jumps with supply shocks.
Our results fall into three categories. First, we show that the risk premia help explain the crosssection of equity
returns. After controlling for the downside and upside risk premia, the variance risk premium is not a significant risk
factor in the crosssection of stock returns over the 19862014 period. Moreover, the upside risk premium is the most
significant factor and the highlow upside jump risk portfolio portfolio earns an average monthly return of 0.50%,
which is economically quite large. The same pattern holds in subsamples using different break points, with the major
exception that the upside jump risk premium loses its explanatory power after 2008, but the variance risk premium is
more significant in this period. This is the era of shale revolutionduring which the domestic oil production of the
United States grew substantially.
Second, we evaluate power of variance, upside jump, and downside jump risk premia to predict important mac-
roeconomic variables. We show that the risk premia and their lags are able to predict considerable amount of variation
in GDP growth, consumption growth, and investment growth. The results show that the upside and downside risk
premia are important predictors of macroeconomic variables and adding them to our model increases the predictive
power of the model considerably. The predictive power of the risk premium variables for macro variables is consistent
with, and helps to explain, why these premia are priced factors.
Finally, we show that the premia have power to predict some of the salient measures of oil market fundamentals.
The results show that downside and upside risk premia predict oil futures returns, oil inventory growth, and oil demand
growth. We also observe that the upside jump premium predicts Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries
(OPEC's) aggregate production growth.
2|DATA AND METHODOLOGY
Options prices can be used to estimate the compensation for bearing different types of price risk. For example, a
deltagamma hedged option portfolio is hedged against changes in prices, but exposed to changes in variance, and
hence returns on this portfolio compensate investors for bearing variance risk. In the same fashion, the returns of the
deltavega hedged portfolio of options measures jump risk probabilities (in the risk neutral measure), as it is hedged
against the risks of price (delta) and variance (vega).
EBRAHIMI AND PIRRONG
|
1283

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT