Offshoring and the Skill‐premium: Evidence from Individual Workers’ Data

Published date01 October 2016
AuthorTommaso Tempesti
Date01 October 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12298
Offshoring and the Skill-premium:
Evidence from Individual Workers’ Data
Tommaso Tempesti
Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts Lowell, Lowell, MA, USA
1. INTRODUCTION
DURING the 1980s, wage inequality in the United States went up markedly. One of the
reasons behind this surge in inequality was the increase in the relative demand for skill.
1
Even though labour economists have not agreed on the relative importance of the possible
explanations for this phenomenon, they tend to rule out that international trade was an impor-
tant factor. In their undergraduate textbook, Ehrenberg and Smith (2005, p. 504) write that
the ‘findings among economists who have analyzed the effects of trade on inequality are not
unanimous, but the predominant conclusion is that the contributions of international trade to
the changes in wage inequality after 1980 were rather small’.
2
Indeed, early studies found the
importance of trade in final goods to be minor.
3
However, in a seminal paper, Feenstra and
Hanson (1999) (FH henceforth) find a sizable effect of trade in intermediate manufactured
inputs on the relative demand for skill in the United States during the 1980s. Given that this
recent result stands in contrast to the previous literature on the subject, the ‘case’ concerning
the importance of trade on wage inequality has been reopened. This work aims at bringing
new empirical evidence to this debate.
This paper studies the effect of offshoring on the skill-premium, using individual workers’
data from the March Current Population Survey (March CPS henceforth).
4
The advantage of
this strategy is twofold. First, the March CPS has been widely used by labour economists to
document the evolution of the skill-premium over time (See e.g. Katz and Autor, 1999). How-
ever, except for Ebenstein et al. (2009), whose contribution I discuss below, the Current Pop-
ulation Survey has not been used to address the importance of the effect of offshoring of
I thank the members of my Ph.D. dissertation committee at Vanderbilt University, Robert Driskill,
Yanqin Fan, Andrea Moro and Joel Rodrigue for their help and support on this project. I also thank
two anonymous referees, Eric Bond, Bob Hammond, Sangsoo Park, seminar participants at Vanderbilt
University, participants to the 3rd ACE International Conference in December 2009 in Hong Kong and
participants to the April 2011 Midwest Trade Meetings at the University of Notre Dame for their useful
comments and suggestions on previous versions of this paper. All errors are mine.
1
Acemoglu (2002a) documents the increase in the US skill-premium, defined as the wage difference
between workers with college education and workers with only a high-school degree. He also argues that
this increase is mainly due to an increase in the relative demand for skill rather than to a decrease in the
relative supply of skill.
2
In his review of the literature on the subject, Acemoglu (2002a, p. 52) argues that ‘increased interna-
tional trade by itself is not the cause of the changes in the US wage structure’ even though he then adds
that trade may have had a more indirect role on wage inequality by affecting the skill bias of
technological change.
3
See the studies discussed in Acemoglu (2002a, p. 5354) An exception, not discussed in Acemoglu
(2002a), is Revenga (1992) who finds a significant impact of import prices of final goods on
employment and wages.
4
I use the term offshoring to indicate trade in intermediate inputs.
©2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
1628
The World Economy (2016)
doi: 10.1111/twec.12298
The World Economy
manufacturing on the skill-premium.
5
This may also have contributed to the fact that, even
after the contribution of FH, many labour economists seem to be still sceptical about the role
of trade on wage inequality in the United States.
6
It is natural to address this gap in the litera-
ture by making use of the March CPS data set.
Second, and more substantially, individual workers’ data allow me to assess a limitation of
FH’s contribution. Their work relies on workers’ data that are aggregated at the industry level,
which does not allow one to control for demographic compositional changes of the labour
force within industries that may be spuriously correlated with offshoring. To illustrate the
potential importance of this, consider the following example. We know as a stylised fact that
wages are increasing in work experience (see, for example, Murphy and Welch, 1990). Sup-
pose that, for reasons unrelated to offshoring, young graduates do not enter a certain industry
where offshoring happens to go up: we observe offshoring going up and the skill-premium
going up, but this is just a spurious correlation. In the above scenario, the estimat es in FH of
the effect of trade on wage inequality would be biased upwards.
To overcome this problem, I merge the March CPS data set, a large representative sample
of the US population, with industry-level variables such as offshoring trade and a proxy for
skill-biased technological change, which is usually indicated as one of the main factors driv-
ing the increase in the skill-premium. As FH, I focus on the 197990 period and on offshor-
ing trade in manufacturing, abstracting from the services sector.
7
In order to motivate my
regression approach, I use the simple model in Feenstra (2004, Ch. 4) to show how offshoring
may affect the relative wage of skilled labour.
Related papers are Lovely and Richardson (2000), Kosteas (2008) and Crin
o (2010).
Lovely and Richardson (2000) and Kosteas (2008) use, respectively, the Panel Study of
Income Dynamics and the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth to study the effect of inter-
national trade and offshoring on wages. These longitudinal data sets allow them to control for
individual fixed effects that may affect wages.
8
Using individual fixed effects, however, has
also its limitations, in that the skill-premium is identified by a small subset of workers, that
is, those workers whose education changes in the data set. Moreover, some of the recorded
5
The first paper that uses the March CPS to address the importance of globalisation on the skill-
premium in the United States is, to my knowledge, Goldberg and Tracy (2003). They study the effect of
exchange rate fluctuations, and not of offshoring trade per se, on the US skill premium. Liu and Trefler
(2011) study the effect of offshoring of services, not of manufacturing, on various labour market out-
comes. Liu and Trefler (2011) also focus on a more recent period than I do.
6
Autor et al. (2006), however, suggest that offshoring may be important to explain the pattern of wage
inequality during the 1990s and beyond. See also Autor et al. (2010).
7
Autor et al. (2008, p. 3) document that the pattern of wage inequality in the United States has changed
in the 1990s with respect to the 1980s. In the 1980s, the increase in inequality was monotonic: higher
incomes rose and lower incomes fell. In the 1990s, the gap between the 90th wage percentile and the
50th wage percentile continued to grow but the gap between the 50th wage percentile and the 10th wage
percentile stabilised. This evidence suggests that at the end of the 1980s, there may have been a struc-
tural break in the evolution of the US wage inequality. Autor et al. (2008) also document a similar pat-
tern for the skill-premium, not just for overall wage inequality. For this reason, I choose to use a trade
model that has the potential of explaining the increase in the skill-premium during the 1980s. Research
points to the importance of service offshoring for the explanation of US wage inequality since the 1990s
[see Crin
o (2009 p. 223), Ahmed et al. (2011) and Liu and Trefler (2011)].
8
The idea is that individuals are endowed with some constant productivity that is unobservable to the
econometrician. If more productive individuals also obtain more schooling, then the estimated return to
education will be biased. See Heckman et al. (2003) for a discussion of this point.
©2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
OFFSHORING AND THE SKILL-PREMIUM 1629

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT