Offshoring and Firm Performance: Evidence from the Italian Manufacturing Industry

Published date01 February 2014
Date01 February 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12067
Offshoring and Firm Performance: Evidence from
the Italian Manufacturing Industry
Ida D’Attoma and Silvia Pacei*
Abstract
The fundamental question of whether offshoring is value enhancing and, more specifically, whether
Italian manufacturing firms that undertake offshoring benefit from higher productivity and profitability is
explored. Using data from the tenth wave of the “Survey on Manufacturing Firms” conducted by
Unicredit-Capitalia, it was found that, compared with domestic firms, firms relocating activities to a
foreign country have different characteristics, and “better” firms might self-select into offshoring decision.
To disentangle the effect of offshoring on firms’ performances from the effect of firm characteristics,
several variants of propensity score matching are used. A mild and insignificant positive effect of
offshoring on profitability was found and also evidence of a statistically significant positive effect of
offshoring on productivity.
1. Introduction
The phenomenon of geographically fragmented production processes has increased
without precedent over the years 1990–2010 because information and communica-
tion technologies (ICTs) have made it possible to divide the value chain and
perform activities in any location (Grossman and Helpman, 2005), while the con-
tinuous decline of transportation costs has facilitated the worldwide flow of goods.
The “globalisation of the value chain” involves the physical fragmentation of pro-
duction and is motivated by a number of factors. One motivating factor is the desire
to reduce operating costs by sourcing inputs from more efficient producers, either
domestic or international, either within or outside the boundary of the firm. Other
factors include the wish to enter emerging markets and access strategic assets that
can help tap into foreign knowledge and the opportunity to exploit fiscal or legal
benefits. The fragmentation of production, notwithstanding the obvious benefits it
offers, also involves costs and risks for those firms involved. Indeed, it gives rise to
considerable business restructuring, including the “offshoring” or “international out-
sourcing” of certain functions (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Devel-
opment (OECD), 2007).
The phenomenon of offshoring dates back to the beginning of the 1970s, when it
involved economies characterized by large-scale enterprises and relatively high labor
costs, such as those of the USA (Levitt, 1983). In the actual period, the increasing
level of competition in international markets has also compelled manufacturing firms
in countries with salaries below those of the USA, such as Italy, to take advantage of
lower production costs abroad. This was initially true for the largest firms, but it is
now also true for small- and medium-sized firms, which represent the majority of
* D’Attoma: Department of Statistical Sciences, University of Bologna, via Belle Arti 41-40126, Bologna,
Italy. Tel: +39-051-2094613; Fax: +39-051-232153; E-mail: Ida.dattoma2@unibo.it. Pacei: Department of
Statistical Sciences, University of Bologna, via Belle Arti 41-40126- Bologna, Italy.
Review of Development Economics, 18(1), 29–44, 2014
DOI:10.1111/rode.12067
© 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
manufacturers in a country such as Italy and have proven capable of splitting up the
production cycle without incurring any substantial diseconomies (Mariotti et al.,
2008). International outsourcing has emerged as a new type of trade in the years
1990–2010 and today trade in intermediate products is more important than trade in
finished products, so that the expression “Made in X” should be replaced by a more
appropriate term “Made in X, Y and Z” or disappear altogether (Kierzkowski and
Chen, 2010).
Various theories have been posited regarding offshoring. The transaction costs ana-
lytical framework, however, represents the main theoretical reference and concen-
trates on the trade-off between costs and benefits associated with different forms of
governance, such as markets, hierarchies (firms), and hybrids (or subcontracting net-
works). According to transaction costs economic theory, offshoring is attractive only
when transaction costs incurred from asset specificity, incomplete contracting and
search efforts are lower than the production costs advantage (Williamson, 1975). In
general, offshoring may have a number of sometimes unexpected effects on the
organization of production, trade flows and international specialization and on the
distribution of income and labor markets, and these effects may vary across activities,
regions and social classes. A particular strand of the literature has focused on how
outsourcing affects growth paths, modifies the production function and hence skill
premium in developed and developing countries, in the theoretical ground of the
classic Heckscher–Ohlin model of intermediate trade (Hu et al., 2005; Sayek and
S¸ ener, 2006; Tang, 2012).
The relationship between offshoring and firms’ productivity has been studied by
international production theorists. The results show that higher international
involvement tends to be associated with higher productivity at any given level of
corporate innovativeness, as gains typically arise from the exploitation of the com-
parative advantages and economies of scale offered by external suppliers (Grossman
and Helpman, 2005). Goods and services may be more efficiently produced in
another country and, consequently, imported at a lower price. This access to better,
cheaper and more varied (final and intermediate) inputs helps improve firms’ prod-
uctivity. In addition, by offshoring, firms may focus on their core skills and thus
increase their level of innovation. Several studies (Hijzen, 2006; Castellani and
Zanfei, 2007; Olsen, 2006) have found a positive correlation between productivity,
outsourcing, R&D expenditures and, hence, innovation processes. Nevertheless, the
sign and the size of the effect of offshoring on companies’ accounting figures have
seldom been studied in a systematic, in-depth manner (Olsen, 2006). One reason for
this is that these variables can only be revealed by empirical studies conducted at
the firm level, and it is generally rather difficult to measure offshoring, as firms are
sometimes reluctant to offer details on their offshoring policies (OECD, 2007) and
public surveys necessary to measure offshoring are only available in few OECD
countries (Daveri and Jona-Lasinio, 2008). Because of the lack of appropriate data
on shifted activities, measures of offshoring are often based on trade flows, i.e. a
consequence of offshoring rather than the shift of the activity itself. Imported inter-
mediates ignore causes of offshoring that do not give rise to imports and include
imports that are not the result of offshoring. In addition, focusing on intermediates
implies leaving out cases where the final stage of the production process is offshored
(Michel and Rycx, 2012). Moreover, imported intermediate inputs considered in
value terms are a biased measure of offshoring if activities are offshored because
imported intermediate inputs are cheaper than domestically produced intermediate
inputs (Michel and Rycx, 2012).
30 Ida D’Attoma and Silvia Pacei
© 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT