Offset Developers, Critics Could Both Benefit by Fixes

AuthorMichael Wara
PositionAssistant Professor at Stanford Law School, where he teaches environmental and property law
Pages53-53
MAY/JUNE 2010 Page 53
Copyright © 2010, Environmental Law Institute®, Washington, D.C. www.eli.org.
Reprinted by permission from The Environmental Forum®, May/June 2010
Th e fo r u m
ductions would presumably have
occurred anyway, meaning they cant
of‌fset other emissions). e same
conclusion applies to voluntary mar-
kets, even though they’re not techni-
cally capped.
Additionality is not rocket sci-
ence, but applying it ef‌fectively
requires a policy decision about how
to balance the inevitably compet-
ing objectives. Policymakers have
too often taken the free lunch way
out of assuming we can design a
perfect system, inadvertently setting
a hurdle that no of‌fset program can
ever meet. Critics then play gotcha,
searching out questionable of‌fset
projects, and characterizing the
whole program as fraudulent. at’s
not necessarily any more appropriate
than condemning home pregnancy
test kits because they occasionally
give an incorrect result. e idea of
perfect policy of‌fers a free lunch and
makes for good rhetoric, but lousy
climate change mitigation.
In 1998 we lost the opportunity
to incentivize companies through
federal early-action legislation to
pursue GHG reductions in advance
of regulations. Many in industry
wanted credit for many things they
clearly would have done anyway.
Many environmental groups, fearing
too loose a policy, wanted to allow
credits for virtually nothing. e net
result was a failure to enact policy
that could have materially contrib-
uted to climate change mitigation
ef‌forts.
Are we on the same path with of‌f-
sets, where players concerned almost
exclusively with compliance costs
push to count almost everything as
an of‌fset, while players primarily in-
terested in environmental perfection
push to allow almost nothing to be
counted? Climate change is too seri-
ous a problem for us to again accept
an outcome that serves neither busi-
ness nor environmental interests.
Mark Trexler is Director of Climate Strate-
gies and Markets at Det Norske Veritas
(U.S.A.), a global risk-management rm.
Of‌fset Developers,
Critics Could Both
Benef‌it by Fixes
M W
Carbon of‌fsets, especially
international of‌fsets, of-
fer the promise of reduc-
ing the cost of developed
country greenhouse gas
reduction goals. While promising in
theory, real international of‌fsets pro-
duced by the Clean Development
Mechanism have failed to deliver
because of persistent doubts about
their quality. Are the claimed reduc-
tions real? Have they been verif‌ied
properly? ere has been enormous
debate around these issues but so far,
not much resolution.
Environmental organizations are
justif‌ied in criticizing a slew of proj-
ects that have made it through the
system despite serious questions as
to whether they would credit busi-
ness-as-usual behavior. At the same
time, of‌fset developers are rightly
outraged about high and uncertain
regulatory risks to their projects cre-
ated by a shifting legal and regulato-
ry landscape. ere is cause and ef-
fect here: doubts about quality lead
to changing standards. Ultimately,
since demand for compliance grade
of‌fsets is a political decision, these
doubts need to be addressed if the
CDM or a successor is to endure.
e good news is that both
problems — lack of environmental
credibility for NGOs and high and
unpredictable regulatory risk for
of‌fset project developers — might
be addressed by one change to the
CDM. What the mechanism needs
is a fair and transparent appellate
process that grants standing to a
wide array of interested parties and
that creates precedents that will bind
future decisionmakers.
Today, environmental groups par-
ticipate in the CDM in two ways:
by commenting at the validation
stage of project applications and
by taking pot shots at the overall
quality of the CDM in the arena of
public opinion, often to devastating
af‌fect.
Comments during validation can
be and are routinely ignored. Criti-
cism of already registered projects
cannot create a better system, except
indirectly, and may undermine sup-
port for international solutions to
greenhouse gas emissions. A healthi-
er of‌fset regulatory process, both for
the environment and for project de-
velopers’ prof‌itability, would foster
buy-in on the part of NGOs while
at the same time creating a body of
precedent that would reduce regula-
tory risk for project developers.
Access to an appellate body for
NGOs would give them a real stake
in the CDM and create a sense of
ownership that is currently lacking.
Having NGOs in the system would
also, of necessity, increase of‌fset
quality by providing a powerful
check to project developers and by
empowering the third-party verif‌iers
in their employ.
Of‌fset developers worry about
opening a f‌loodgate of challenges.
Evidence from the Forest Steward-
ship Council and the Marine Stew-
ardship Council, both of which have
appellate review with broad stand-
ing, indicates otherwise. NGOs
have limited resources. Assuming
that appellate decisions would bind
future decisionmakers, the more
likely result is a system with clear,
albeit tougher, rules that would lead
to higher quality of‌fsets created with
lower risk and hence, lower transac-
tion costs.
e NGO and the of‌fset de-
veloper communities would both
be better of‌f in such a system. e
alternative is continued erosion of
public conf‌idence in of‌fsets as a tool
of climate mitigation.
Michael Wara, Ph.D., is an Assistant
Professor at Stanford Law School, where he
teaches environmental and property law.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT