O'Connell Early Settlement Offers: Toward Realistic Numbers and Two‐Sided Offers

Date01 June 2010
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1740-1461.2010.01182.x
Published date01 June 2010
O’Connell Early Settlement Offers: Toward
Realistic Numbers and Two-Sided Offersjels_1182379..401
Bernard Black, David A. Hyman, and Charles Silver*
In a prior article in this journal, we estimated the effect of an “O’Connell” early settlement
offer program on payouts in medical malpractice litigation. Using Texas data and a base set
of assumptions, we predicted that early offers would result in a 16 percent (20 percent)
decline in payouts in currently tried (settled) cases. The overall decline came almost entirely
from a sharp drop in payouts in cases with small economic damages. We compared our results
with the estimate by Hersch, O’Connell, and Viscusi (2007) (HOV) of a 70 percent reduction
in payouts, reconciled the two estimates, and explained why HOV’s estimate reflected the
compound effects of a series of unreasonable assumptions. In a reply in this journal, Hersch,
O’Connell, and Viscusi (2010) (HOV-2) complain that we misunderstand both the early offer
proposal and their analysis. Remarkably, they do not dispute our estimates, given our
assumptions. In this rebuttal, we defend our assumptions and provide an alternate analysis of
settled cases based on insurer allocations, which also produces an estimated 20 percent
payout decline. We also develop further our proposal for two-sided early offers. This proposal
would reduce the predicted payout decline by about 2 percent in both tried and settled cases.
We explain in greater detail the problems with HOV’s analysis. If we correct an error they
made in understanding the Texas data set, and leave their other assumptions unchanged,
their payout decline estimate drops to 30 percent, not far from ours.
I. Introduction
In a prior article in this journal (hereinafter, BHS),1we analyzed an early settlement
proposal that Professor Jeffrey O’Connell has been promoting since 1982.2Under his
proposal, defendants can offer to settle for full economic damages plus attorney fees,
possibly with a minimum damages offer in some cases. Plaintiffs who refuse the offer
*Address correspondence to Bernard Black; email: bblack@northwestern.edu; from the fall of 2010, Black will be
Nicholas J. Chabraja Professor at Northwestern University, Law School and Kellogg School of Management. Black is
currently Hayden W. Head Regents Chair for Faculty Excellence, University of Texas School of Laws, and Professor
of Finance, University of Texas, Red McCombs School of Business. Hyman is Richard and Marie Corman Professor
of Law and Professor of Medicine, University of Illinois; Silver is McDonald Endowed Chair in Civil Procedure,
University of Texas Law School.
We thank Hyun Kim for superb research assistance and Vicky Knox of the Texas Department of Insurance for her
answers to our many questions about the TDI database.
1Black et al. (2009). <http://www3.interscience.wiley.com/cgi-bin/fulltext/123214961/PDFSTART>.
2O’Connell (1982).
Journal of Empirical Legal Studies
Volume 7, Issue 2, 379–401, June 2010
379
face a large stick in the form of a heightened burden of proof—they must prove gross
negligence beyond a reasonable doubt, making the offer one “that can’t be refused.”3Our
article responded to an empirical study by O’Connell and co-authors Joni Hersch and W.
Kip Viscusi (hereinafter, HOV), where they estimated that an early offer program would
reduce payouts and defense costs by roughly 70 percent.4
In BHS, we estimated that, under a base set of assumptions and using basically the same
data set as HOV, an early offer program would produce a 16 percent (20 percent) overall
decline in payouts in currently tried (settled) cases. We also provided sensitivity analyses
showing how this estimate would vary depending on program details and on changes in our
assumptions. Under no plausible set of assumptions was the estimated payout decline even
close to HOV’s estimate. We showed: (1) that the overall payout decline would come mostly
from large drops in payouts in cases with “small” economic damages of $0–$100,000; and (2)
elderly and deceased plaintiffs would experience large payout declines, with much more
limited effects on babies, children, and employed adults in nondeath cases.5
Why do our results differ so greatly from HOV’s? In BHS, we concluded that HOV’s
payout decline estimates reflect the compound effects of a series of unreasonable assump-
tions, including: (1) only one-third of paid damages are economic; (2) no adjustment of
payouts for the time value of money; (3) current payouts include full payment of economic
damages; (4) a fee of 10 percent of economic damages (9 percent of gross payout) is a
market-clearing price for the services of plaintiffs’ attorneys; (5) plaintiffs incur no out-of-
pocket litigation costs; and (6) no minimum damages offer in many cases.
In a reply in this journal, Hersch, O’Connell, and Viscusi (hereinafter, HOV-2)
challenge some of our assumptions and complain that we misunderstood their proposal
and “misrepresent[] fundamental aspects of [their] analysis.”6Remarkably, they do not
dispute our estimates given our assumptions. The central question is, therefore: Whose
assumptions are more reasonable—ours or theirs? In this rebuttal, we defend our assump-
tions and analysis, provide additional sensitivity tests, and develop an alternate analysis of
early offers in settled cases, based on insurer allocations of damages. Our alternate analysis,
which also produces an estimated 20 percent payout decline in settled cases, responds to
HOV’s concern with whether one can reliably extrapolate from tried cases to settled cases.
Extrapolating from tried cases and relying on insurer allocations have different strengths
and weaknesses; we consider both approaches to be reasonable. As it turns out, the two
approaches produce similar results.
We also develop further our proposal for two-sided early offers, which HOV dismiss,
and show that it does not have the flaws they attribute to it. Two-sided offers would better
3Hence the title of Professor O’Connell’s initial article, which begins “Offers That Can’t Be Refused.” Id.
4Hersch et al. (2007); see also the similar estimates in O’Connell and Born (2008) and O’Connell and Robinette
(2008).
5All amounts in BHS and this rebuttal are in 1988 dollars; to convert to 2008 dollars, multiply by 1.82.
6Herschet al.(2010:164) (abstract). <http://www3.interscience.wiley.com/cgi-bin/fulltext/123294628/PDFSTART>.
380 Black et al.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT