Note About Citations in Text

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ajes.12082_4
Published date01 October 2014
Date01 October 2014
The AMERICAN JOURNAL of
ECONOMICS and SOCIOLOGY
Published QUARTERLY in the interest of constructive
synthesis in the social sciences, under grants from the FRANCIS
NEILSON Fund and the ROBERT SCHALKENBACH FOUNDATION.
Founded in 1941
Volume 73 October 2014 Number 4
Editor’s Introduction
An element of confusion entered the modern understanding of taxa-
tion in the late 19th century and continues to confuse even the wisest
of our professors and pundits. As long as that confusion distorts our
thoughts, leaders of all ideological persuasions will try dozens of tax
“reforms,” but none will achieve the desired results. What is missing
is not some special technique. Rather, what has been lost is the
wisdom about the nature of taxation that the French Physiocrats and
their student, Adam Smith, carried over from the medieval view of
society as an organism. This work by Dr. Terence Dwyer enables us
to share in that wisdom.
Adam Smith is often regarded as the first philosopher of capitalism,
an advocate of a free enterprise system in which private ownership
and unfettered exchange would unleash the potential for innovation
and production that is latent in every society. However, Adam Smith
would not have favored any of the tax plans proposed by economists
or politicians since World War II, neither from progressives nor
conservatives. He disagreed with the conservative ideology that taxes
should fall on consumption items and on the wages of working
people, leaving the rich untaxed for the purpose of promoting capital
formation. He also disagreed with progressives who want to raise
taxes on the rich by taxing top-income earners.
American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 73, No. 4 (October, 2014).
DOI: 10.1111/ajes.12082
© 2014 American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc.
Adam Smith’s view was based on a medieval system that regarded
taxation as evil, but sometimes necessary. A tax in the medieval
lexicon meant a slice taken out of wages or an additional charge on
a daily commodity such as beer or salt. It was, in short, a payment
made out of ordinary income by common people. We have grown so
accustomed to fees of that sort that we cannot imagine government
financed in any other way.
How is it possible to pay the expenses of government without
taxes? It is really quite simple: the government owns natural
resources, leases them, and uses the revenue to finance its opera-
tions. That is how it worked in the Middle Ages. The governing
institutions—the aristocracy and the Church—owned all the land, and
their operating costs were financed by land rents. In effect, the
decentralized governments of the time owned the land in public trust,
leased it to private farmers, mill operators, and shopkeepers, then
used the lease fees to pay public costs, including support of the poor.
Instead of a commoner paying rent to a landlord and taxes to the
government, only one payment was required, which covered both
functions. In the early modern period, this system broke down. Land
became private property, held without reciprocal obligations, and
new taxes for government were instituted on top of the lease fees that
commoners had to pay landowners to occupy land. Land-holding in
the feudal era could be justified in relation to the common good
because being a landholder meant taking on responsibilities. In the
modern era, freehold landownership without tax obligations required
a new justification, but it was not supplied by the earliest architects
of capitalism, who still regarded land rents as the basis of financing
government.
Adam Smith in Wealth of Nations (BK V, Ch. 1, ¶230; Ch. 2, ¶14)
pointed out that landrent had always been the basis of government:
The rent of land, however, is, according to some, the sole fund, and,
according to others, the principal fund, from which, in all great monar-
chies, the exigencies of the state must be ultimately supplied. . . . Land is
a fund of a more stable and permanent nature; and the rent of public lands,
accordingly, has been the principal source of the public revenue of many
a great nation .... From the produce or rent of the public lands, the
ancient republics of Greece and Italy derived, for a long time, the greater
part of that revenue which defrayed the necessary expenses of the
628 The American Journal of Economics and Sociology
commonwealth. The rent of the crown lands constituted for a long time the
greater part of the revenue of the ancient sovereigns of Europe.
Smith realized that, in his own day, the incompetent management of
public lands by government officials would not yield enough revenue
to supply the peacetime needs of nations. However, the land still held
the potential for state finance. Thus, when he described the taxes that
the modern state must levy on top of the leasing of public lands, he
began with “taxes upon the rent of land.”
The property tax remains one of the last vestiges of the archaic
system of financing government and one of the few that taxes wealth.
We can see one element of that history in the term “real estate,” where
the word “real” once meant “royal,” referring to the idea that the king
or queen owned all the land and then leased it out through a hierarchy
of retainers to the populace. The monarch was the personification of
the nation, a symbol of society as a whole. Thus, in a more democratic
era, some constitutions still recognize that the people, via the state,
collectively own the land and other natural resources within that
jurisdiction and that nominal owners hold their titles in trust. That is
why private ownership of land always comes with restrictions. It also
demonstrates that the feudal logic of using gifts of nature on behalf of
the entire populace is still present in our society, but lying dormant.
In this work, Dr. Dwyer provides the tools to enable us to question
the assumptions behind the modern management of the economy.
Although he recognizes Adam Smith’s intellectual debt to medieval
thought, Dwyer certainly does not propose to revert to the feudal
system, not even to restore public ownership of land, forests, fisheries,
petroleum, or any other natural source of economic value. All that is
required is to shift, over a period of time, from taxes on labor and
capital to taxes on land and resources. There is no need to disturb the
market process, which serves as an efficient method of allocating
goods and services to where they are in greatest demand.
What is required is a major change in our thinking about private
property. Recognizing that economies produce a surplus, we need to
ask why everyone is not a beneficiary. Knowing that the means exist
to share the surplus among the entire population, how is it that only
a lucky or ruthless few have managed to claim it for themselves as
private property? In short, the central question is how we can make
Editor’s Introduction 629

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT