No Money, No Representation: A Case Study of Zeguo Town in China

Date01 March 2018
DOI10.1177/0032329218754511
AuthorJing Ye
Published date01 March 2018
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329218754511
Politics & Society
2018, Vol. 46(1) 81 –99
© 2018 SAGE Publications
Reprints and permissions:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0032329218754511
journals.sagepub.com/home/pas
Article
No Money, No Representation:
A Case Study of Zeguo
Town in China
Jing Ye
University of International Business and Economics
Abstract
Authoritarian regimes rely on fiscal resources to build patronage networks. And
so it is with China. Budget making is usually dominated by government leaders.
However, some local governments in recent years have invited ordinary people to
review budgets and even to determine parts of budgets. Why would local leaders
make themselves accountable to their constituencies in an authoritarian setting? Why
would local governments in China tie their own hands? Using detailed description of
a township government, this article argues that fiscal affluence based on land is an
important factor for local governments in launching fiscal reform. Richer areas have
become more fiscally accountable by opening up new discussion and encouraging
citizen participation.
Keywords
local accountability, lands, fiscal affluence, participatory fiscal reform
Corresponding Author:
Jing Ye, University of International Business and Economics, Chaoyang District, Beijing, China.
Email: yejing@uibe.edu.cn
754511PASXXX10.1177/0032329218754511Politics & SocietyYe
research-article2018
82 Politics & Society 46(1)
Scholars increasingly recognize that a strict dichotomy between democracy and
authoritarianism is overly simple and naive.1 These two broad categories not only
include separate subtypes but are also, in reality, intertwined. Democratic countries
may have subnational authoritarian enclaves.2 At the same time, authoritarian coun-
tries incorporate democratic practices.3 China is a very interesting case in this regard.
Some scholars have argued that Leninist state institutions have maintained the auton-
omy of the state and escaped social constraints in post-Mao China.4 However, that is
not in fact the case. It is true that the overall political system remains intact, but politi-
cal change in China has been occurring incrementally and gradually, especially at the
local level.5 Village committees were launched in the late 1980s.6 Local People’s
Congresses have become substantively representative.7 Local People’s Political
Consultative Conferences now serve as a direct form of political participation and
consultation with social elites.8 And similarly to other democratic countries, China has
an operationally autonomous civil society to work with local governments.9
Democratic practices are evident even in the fiscal field. China has been regarded
as one of the least transparent countries with regard to fiscal reports and as having little
engagement with the public. It is understandable that an authoritarian regime would
rely on fiscal resources to buy supporters.10 Therefore, for many years, budgeting has
been regarded as an exclusive instrument the government uses to ensure its authority
and to prevent public involvement in China.11 In the open budget index, China was
ranked ninety-first among 102 countries worldwide in 2015, much lower than other
equivalent developing countries such as Brazil (sixth), Russia (eleventh), and India
(fifty-third).12 In this broad scenario, however, there are now some grassroots fiscal
reforms. Local governments in several regions have invited ordinary citizens to review
budgets and even to decide parts of budgets. Such regions include towns and districts
in Shanghai, Henan, Zhejiang, Jiangsu, Heilongjiang, Sichuan, Beijing, Yunnan, and
Guangdong provinces.
In most of these cases, local government leaders play pivotal roles. That fact is
especially puzzling given that local government leaders can reap two kinds of benefits
when they dominate the fiscal decision-making process. First, they can take advantage
of fiscal resources to secure political achievements for themselves, leading to promo-
tion. Because promotion of local leaders is controlled by the nomenklatura system,
local leaders are more accountable to the upper hierarchical levels.13 Fiscal resources
provide tools that can be used to impress superiors. For instance, local leaders are
believed to spend more money in the later parts of their tenures to improve their pros-
pects for official promotion.14 In addition, local governments spend more money on
infrastructure and less on investment in human capital and public services, because
infrastructure is more visible to higher level officials.15 Second, as Wan, Ye, and
Franco noted, neoguanxilism has become a main mechanism of resource allocation in
China.16 When they dominate fiscal allocation, local leaders distribute fiscal resources
on the basis of informal networks. For that reason, budget making dominated by gov-
ernment leaders should be among the most resilient practices in the Chinese political
system. How would engaging the public in the process be possible in China? Why
would local leaders in an authoritarian setting make themselves accountable to the

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT