New Life for the Octopus: How Voting Rules Sustain the Power of California's Big Landowners

Published date01 May 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ajes.12152
AuthorMerrill Goodall,Mason Gaffney
Date01 May 2016
New Life for the Octopus: How Voting Rules Sustain
the Power of California’s Big Landowners
By MASON GAFFNEY and MERRILL GOODALL*
ABSTRACT. The concentrated ownership of farmland has influenced rural
life in the state of California for more than a century. Reformers have
introduced measures to counteract that concentration, such as acreage
limits on farms receiving water from federally funded projects. Large
landowners have fought back with policies that have protected their ability
to amass and maintain their empires. In the first part of this article, Mason
Gaffney presents this historical background in broad outlines. In the
second part, Merrill Goodall explains an important policy that preserves the
power of entrenched interests: water districts that are governed by a board
elected by a voting system that allots one vote to each dollar of land value.
In these districts, a tiny handful of landowners is able to control a public
agency without opposition and without the need to persuade other voters.
Origins of Concentrated Landownership in
California
By MASON GAFFNEY
California became a state in 1850. Even before that, Spanish and Mexi-
can governance had created large landed estates. The Spanish had
transferred their hacienda system to the New World, and in 1846, the
Treaty of Guadalupe-Hidalgo let 800 Mexicans retain title to 8,000,000
acres of land after the United States took control of the territory. The
fruits of the old feudal system were adopted by the new sovereign, and
the results are still with us today. Tejon, Flint-Bixby, Irvine, Stearns, and
Hearst all operated large ranches on land that was acquired as Spanish
*Gaffney: Professor of economics at University of California, Riverside. email: m.
gaffney@dslextreme.com. Author of After the Crash: Designing a Depression-Free
Economy (2009) and The Corruption of Economics (1999). Goodall: Deceased 2002.
Goodall taught political science at Claremont Graduate University. Two of his areas of
research interest were water policy in California and public administration in Nepal.
American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 75, No. 3 (May, 2016).
DOI: 10.1111/ajes.12152
V
C2016 American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc.
land grants in the brief period of transition from Mexican to American
control (McWilliams 2000: 13–14).
Migrants coming to California or gold miners leaving the mountains
and searching for work on a farm learned by 1860 that the best farm-
land had already been preempted. Preempted, but not farmed. Only 1
million acres out of 40 million were being cultivated in 1863. The
remainder were being underutilized by the land barons who had
gained title earlier. By 1870, the railroads owned 20,000,000 acres of
California, granted by Congress as a method of paying for construction.
In theory, the railroads only owned alternating sections of land, check-
erboard style, but settlers who tried to farm in the other sections soon
learned that the shadow of the railroads was cast over all of the land
along their routes. The state government of California was fully com-
plicit in the misuse of private authority, in large part because officials
were elected with money from the land barons (McWilliams 2000: 12,
15–18).
Federal Water Policy in the 19
th
Century
The federal government was also not very helpful to the millions of
farmers who were looking for land in western states. For example, the
Department of Interior relinquished its riparian claims on upstream
waters in mountainous areas, but that merely strengthened the titles of
downstream users who had claims, of which the large landowners
were primary holders.
Various populist reform measures were adopted at the federal and
state level to limit the power of large landowners in California or in
other western states that depended on federal water. Congress adopted
the Preemption Act, Homestead Act, and Morrill Act with the view of
making more land available to settlers who would work the land. The
federal government recognized that settlers were necessary to solidify
territorial claims, particularly against foreign powers that might other-
wise encroach on U.S. territory. But despite that incentive, the U.S. Con-
gress, influenced by wealthy interests, consistently undermined
western settlement by creating loopholes that would permit agglomera-
tion of large landholdings. For example, under the Reclamation Act of
1902, farmowners were not supposed to receive subsidized water for
The American Journal of Economics and Sociology650
tracts of land exceeding 160 acres, but in fact, farms as large as 40,000
acres benefited through the use of loopholes (U.S. GAO 1972: 11).
The Great Landowners and Their Water
State law in California was originally designed to allocate water accord-
ing to need, with the idea being that landowners needed lots of water
for dryland irrigation. According to the ancient doctrine of appropria-
tive use (first in time, first in right), landowners had a claim on water to
the extent that they used it on their land. The right to water was based
on the size of a farm. There was no incentive to use water efficiently.
Quite the contrary. The appropriative doctrine encouraged wasteful
uses, such as growing alfalfa, rice, irrigated pasture, or other water-
intensive crops in a desert.
Another wasteful method of monopolizing water rights in the 19
th
century was through the use of riparian rights, which are proportional
to the acreage adjacent to a body of water, including all ofthe backlying
land if owned by the riparian. Riparian rights “go with the land” and do
not require any usage. Using riparian rights, Henry Miller (of Miller &
Lux) effectively preempted large quantities of water and denied the
farmers not abutting the San Joaquin River rights to irrigation water. His
amassed water rights there and elsewhere permitted him to build an
empire, owning 1.2million acres (Igler 2001: 4).
I have discussed in my previous writings (Gaffney 2009: Ch. 1) the
effectiveness of property taxes as a method of limiting large landhold-
ings. Miller and Lux were equally cognizant of that relationship. Igler
(2001: 70) summarizes how they handled the problem:
For a corporation that owned nearly half a million of acres of land by 1875,
property taxes were unquestionably a source of great anxiety. [As a result of
reforms], between 1870 and 1872, tax assessments on land in California
jumped from $227,538,127 to $636,378,114. This increase could have forced
large landowners to sell off property. But county residents elected the prop-
erty assessors. and given the largest landowners’ political clout at the local
level, assessors were often responsive to their will. ... [In Fresno County, an
associate of Miller & Lux informed them that] “it would undoubtedly be to
your advantage that John Stroud be elected for Assessor. He can be man-
aged.” ...[Through their network of c ontrols over water allocators in Fresno
New Life for the Octopus 651

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT