New Firm Performance and the Replacement of Founder‐CEOs

AuthorPeter Thompson,Jing Chen
Date01 September 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/sej.1203
Published date01 September 2015
NEW FIRM PERFORMANCE AND THE
REPLACEMENT OF FOUNDER-CEOs
JING CHEN1* and PETER THOMPSON2
1Department of Innovation and Organizational Economics, Copenhagen Busi-
ness School, Copenhagen, Denmark
2Scheller College of Business, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia,
U.S.A.
We study the causes and consequences of the replacement of founder-CEOs in a sample of
4,172 Danish start-ups. We propose that founder-CEO replacement is driven in part by
mismatches between business quality and founder ability. Our framework suggests that
replacements are more likely among the worst- and best-performing firms, with low (high)-
ability founders replaced by manager with higher (lower) ability. Replacement is not unam-
biguously associated with better subsequent performance. Firms that replaced the founder
were much morelikely to fail, but the surviving firms among them grew considerably faster. Our
empirical results are consistent with these proposed predictions. Copyright © 2015 Strategic
Management Society
INTRODUCTION
Why do entrepreneurs cede operating control to spe-
cialist managers? What factors influence the likeli-
hood of founder-manager succession? What
implications does the departure of the founder have
for subsequent business performance? And what
happens to founders after they have left? Answers
to these questions not only have pertinent implica-
tions for practitioners, but they also have the poten-
tial to advance academic research on entrepreneurial
motivation and its relationship with business perfor-
mance. This article examines the causes and conse-
quences of founder-CEO replacement among new
businesses that are generally small, almost invariably
not financed by venture capital, and generally not at
risk of an IPO event. We know surprisingly little
about founder turnover among such firms.1
Founder turnover events have been studied exten-
sively in other types of firms. A small literature that
has focused on high-growth and VC-backed firms 2
finds that a founder is most likely to be replaced by
a manager after a period of rapid expansion (Boeker
and Karichalil 2002) or upon attainment of critical
milestones, such as completion of product develop-
ment or securing new rounds of outside funding
(Wasserman 2003). More important, perhaps, is that
founder turnover is typically motivated by an expec-
tation among stakeholders that the firm is likely to
undergo an episode of transformational growth in the
Keywords: entrepreneurship; business creation; founder turn-
over; CEO turnover
*Correspondence to: Jing Chen, Department of Innovation and
Organizational Economics, Copenhagen Business School,
Kilevej 14, 2000 Frederiksberg, Denmark. E-mail: jc.ino@
cbs.dk.
1For convenience, we will use the term ‘founder turnover’ to
describe an event where a founder who had been managing the
firm as his/her primary occupation rescinds operating control
while maintaining ownership. Replacements will be referred to
as ‘managers.’
2Of course, executive turnover in established, typically public,
firms has been studied extensively for many years (e.g., Hofer
1980, Chen and Hambrick, 2012). There is also an active lit-
erature on succession in family-owned businesses, but the con-
cerns of this literature are rather different from those in which
executive control is passed outside the founder’s family. See
Handler (1994) for a review.
bs_bs_banner
Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal
Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 9: 243–262 (2015)
Published online in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com). DOI: 10.1002/sej.1203
Copyright © 2015 Strategic Management Society
near future. Indeed, a portion of the literature explic-
itly samples on such expectations by studying only
firms that are preparing for IPOs (Nelson, 2003; Jain
and Tabak, 2008; Pollock, Fund, and Baker, 2009).
The extant research lacks findings that we can
confidently extrapolate to the typical small and non-
VC-backed businesses that are predominant in every
economy. First, founders of VC-financed firms
appear to be replaced at markedly higher rates than
firms that are not subject to significant control by
outside equity investors (Hellmann and Puri, 2002;
Boeker and Wiltbank, 2005). This difference, as
Hellmann and Puri (2002) have argued, highlights
the role of VC investors in professionalizing top
management teams at entrepreneurial firms. But it
also implies that the replacement decisions at
VC-financed firms are often reached based on inves-
tors’ beliefs about what is best for the businesses,
rather than on the motives of entrepreneurs. Second,
founder turnover at VC-backed firms are often
accompanied by a phenomenon termed ‘the paradox
of entrepreneurial success’ (Wasserman 2003). That
is, the more quickly entrepreneurs become success-
ful, the more likely they are to be replaced by pro-
fessional CEOs. However, the majority of small
businesses created in the economy are unlikely to
undergo transformations of the sort that appear to
motivate many founder turnover events at
VC-financed firms. Third, VC-financed firms are not
random draws from the firm population—they are
more likely to grow substantially, they are better
financed, and their founders and employees, on
average, have more human capital. Correlations
between variables estimated from a sample drawn
from the upper tail of the quality distribution may
not hold in other segments of the population, espe-
cially when there are possibilities for nonmonotonic
relationships in the population as a whole. Lastly, it
is well known that VC-financed firms account for a
tiny fraction of business launches,3but they play
a much larger role in economic growth, employ-
ment creation, and innovation. As a result, academic
effort to understand the dynamics of control in
VC-financed firms is appropriately disproportionate
to their numbers. Nonetheless, given their numerical
importance, we should also be concerned with the
control dynamics of the typical small business. Pat-
terns of founder turnover among representative busi-
nesses can also provide insights into the forces
governing business transfers.4They are also key to
understanding the expected opportunity costs of
business creation, as well as the dual phenomenas of
serial and portfolio entrepreneurs.
Although the primary contribution of this article is
intended to be empirical, we need a theoretical
framework to guide our empirical analysis and facili-
tate interpretation of the results. Among VC-backed
firms, the goal of founder turnover is generally held
to be resolving mismatches between founders’
managerial skills and the growth expectation of firms
in the near future. We work within this framework
but, because the firms in our sample do not typically
undergo transformational growth, we focus on
current rather than anticipated mismatches. We
suppose that firm performance is a function of the
ability of the founder and the quality of the business
idea. While a founder may be aware of his/her
ability, the quality of the business is not fully
revealed until after it is founded. Ability and quality
are complements in production so that there can
arise mismatches of sufficient magnitude to justify
replacing the founder with a manager who is better
suited to the needs of the business. This framework
yields two types of founder turnover: those in which
a high ability founder hires a less able manager with
a lower opportunity cost of time, and those in which
a low ability founder hires a more capable, but more
expensive, manager. Under conditions we explore in
the next section, turnover may be more likely in the
tails of both the founder ability and firm perfor-
mance distributions. Moreover, turnoverin the lower
tail of the firm performance distribution tends to be
associated with subsequent improvements in firm
performance among surviving firms, while the rela-
tionship is a priori ambiguous in the upper tail.
For our empirical analysis, we construct a sample
of 4,172 Danish businesses created in 1999 and
2000. Compared to previous studies that are con-
fined to small samples within high-tech sectors,5our
sample has a broad coverage of industries. Only 18
percent of businesses included are classified as
3For example, in the United States, 626,771 new businesses
were created in 2008, only 3,276 of which received VC financ-
ing (Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2014; NVCA 2009).
4Founders may sell businesses because they are poorly
matched to the needs of the businesses or because they have
reasons to cash out their equity positions. Looking at founder
turnover in businesses that are not transferred allows us to gain
insights about the first of these two motivations.
5For example, the sample constructed by Wasserman (2003)
consists of 202 Internet firms. Pollock et al. (2009) also study
340 Internet start-ups financed by VCs. Hellmann and Puri
(2002) focus on a sample of 173 high-tech start-ups located in
Silicon Valley.
244 J. Chen and P. Thompson
Copyright © 2015 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J.,9: 243–262 (2015)
DOI: 10.1002/sej

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT