A New Data Set On Competition In National Banking Markets

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/fmii.12030
Published date01 May 2015
Date01 May 2015
A New Data Set On Competition In National Banking
Markets
BYSOFRONIS CLERIDES,MANTHOS D. DELIS,AND SOTIRIOS KOKAS
We estimate the degree of competition in the banking sectors of 148 countries over the
period 1997–2010 using three methods: the Lerner index, the adjusted Lerner index, and
the profit elasticity. Marginal cost estimates required for all methods are obtained using a
flexible semi-parametric methodology. All three indices show that competitiveconditions
in banking deteriorated during the period 1997–2006, improveduntil 2008, and deteriorated
again thereafter.Levels of competition differ across regions and income groups, but there is
gradual convergence over time. Banking system is less competitivein sub-Saharan Africa
and low income countries and more competitive in Europe and Central and South Asia and
OECD countries.
Keywords: Bank market power, competition, world sample.
JEL Classification G2, D40.
I. INTRODUCTION
The issue of banking sector competition has attracted much interest in recent
years, not least because of the financial crisis. Alongside the standard objective
of achieving effective market competition, the issue has additional significance in
banking because of the sector’s crucial role in the allocation of credit. Economic
development relies upon financial intermediation services that link users with
providers of capital and allow consumption decisions to be smoothed over time.
There are at least three key questions of interest in the theoretical and empirical
literature. First, does the degree of bank competition impact the efficiencyof credit
allocation (Cetorelli and Strahan, 2006; Bonnacorsi and Dell’Ariccia, 2004)?
Second, how does the intensity of competition affectthe financial system’s stability
(Keeley, 1990; Boyd and De Nicolo, 2005)? Third, what are the macroeconomic
outcomes of banking-sector competition (Cetorelli, 2004)?
To address these important questions, one first needs to come up with mean-
ingful measures of the intensity of bank competition. Some studies (e.g., Cetorelli
and Strahan, 2006) followed the early industrial organization tradition and used
concentration measures as a proxy for bank competition. There is however a
growing consensus that concentration measures – useful as they may be in re-
vealing important structural characteristics of the industry – are not good proxies
for bank competition (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt and Levine, 2006; Claessens and
Laeven, 2004). Instead, recent literature favors measures like the price-cost mar-
gin or Lerner index (Lerner, 1934), the adjusted-Lerner index (Koetter, Kolari and
Spierdijk, 2012), the H statistic (Panzar and Rosse, 1987), and the profit elasticity
(Boone, Griffith and Harrison, 2005). Computing any of these measures (with the
Corresponding author: Sotirios Kokas, Essex Business School. Email: skokas@essex.ac.uk.
C2015 NewYork University Salomon Center and Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
268 Sofronis Clerides et al.
exception of the H statistic) requires knowledge of marginal cost. Given that data
on marginal cost are not usually available, an important first step in the construc-
tion of a competition index is the estimation of marginal cost using econometric
methods.
The objective of this paper is to present a new set of estimates for bank competi-
tion in 148 countries for the period 1997–2010 and to analyze trends and patterns
in the evolution of competition during that period. Competition is measured in
terms of the Lerner index, the adjusted-Lerner index and the profit elasticity. The
paper contributes to the literature on bank competition in four important ways.
First, we use a novel technique to obtain accurate estimates of marginal cost and
market power for each observation in the sample. The smooth coefficient model
we employ is a semiparametric approach that allows for a flexible cost structure.
Second, we have the broadest coverage compared to existing studies, with 148
countries from 1997 to 2010. While most studies focus on a specific region or
income group, our data set allows studying the degree of within-country bank
competition in a large number of countries. With coverage up to 2010, we are able
to analyze the evolution of bank competition during the financial crisis. Third, we
compute three different indicators favoredby the recent banking literature, namely
the Lerner index, the adjusted-Lerner index and the profit elasticity. Fourth, we
clean the raw data required to estimate these indices from double-counting stem-
ming from mergers and acquisitions, ownership issues, inflexible features of the
Bankscope database, and other problems.
All indices indicate substantive changes in bank competition over time and
across income and regional classification. The Lerner index, the adjusted-Lerner
index and the profit elasticity produce similar overall patterns of competition over
time. We observe a gradual decline in the intensity of competition from 1997 to
2006. The trend reverses for a brief period (2007–2008) but then market power
increases again in 2009 and 2010. This pattern raises interesting questions about
the relationship between competitive conditions and financial stability. Notably,
bank competition seems to weaken during the upward phase of the business
cycle and to become more intense when economic conditions worsen. We do not
formally explore this link in the current work but leave it open as an important
question for future research.
The empirical results also highlight important differences across regions and
income groups. On average, the banking systems of Sub-Saharan Africa are the
least competitive, followed by East Asia and Pacific. Europe and Central and
South Asia have the most competitivebanking sectors. Non-OECD countries with
either high or low income levelshave less competitive banking sectors than middle-
income countries. OECD countries have lowerbank market power overall. Despite
the differences, competition levels across income and regional groups seem to be
converging over tim e.
The three competition measures largely coincide when it comes to the main
overall trends but do differ when compared at a finer level. We do not take a
stand on which index is best. Each measure has its own theoretical interpretation
A New Data Set On Competition In National Banking Markets 269
and its calculation presents different empirical challenges. Rather than propose a
specific measure, we provide (section 2) an extensive discussion of the theoretical
justification for each index that we hope will be a useful guide to potential users
seeking to identify their preferred measure.
The structure of the paper is as follows. Section II presents an overview of bank
competition measures. Section III describes our data and the empirical method-
ology. Section IV presents the empirical results on the various indices of bank
competition. Section V concludes.
II. EMPIRICAL METHODS FOR THE ESTIMATION OF
COMPETITION
Estimation of competition has a long history in industrial organization, dating
back to Lerner (1934). Lerner defined his “index of the degreeof monopoly power”
(or “degree of monopoly” for short) as
Lerneri=Pimci
Pi
,(1)
where Piand mciare firm i’s price and marginal cost respectively. The index
ranges between 0 and 1, with zero corresponding to perfect competition and larger
values reflecting a greater degree of market power. The Lerner index remains to
this day the most widely and popular measure of market power and the intensity
of competition.1The main reasons for its popularity are simplicity, an intuitive
interpretation, and relatively mild data requirements. The Lerner index measures
the ability of an individual bank to charge a price above marginal cost. When
data on prices and marginal cost are available, the Lerner index can be computed
as a simple ratio. Because marginal cost is rarely available, researchers have to
either estimate a cost function or impose equilibrium conditions derived from
theoretical models in order to obtain marginal cost estimates. The former method
is usually used in the banking literature, while the latter is preferred by industrial
organization economists.2In this paper we will follow the banking literature
approach of estimating a cost function.
Koetter,Kolari and Spierdijk (2012) have argued that the conventional approach
of computing the Lerner index assumes both profit efficiency (optimal choice of
prices) and cost efficiency (optimal choice of inputs by firms). As a result, the
estimated price-cost margins do not correctly measure the true extent of market
power. The argument reflects a distinction pointed out by Lerner (1934) himself,
who states that “for practical purposes we must read monopoly power not as
potential monopoly, but as monopoly in force” (p. 170; italics as in the original).
1Throughout the paper we will use market power as a measure of competition intensity.This is usually
an innocuous assumption, although research has shown that the Lerner index does not always point in
the expected direction when competitive conditions change (Stiglitz, 1989; Boone, 2008).
2The use of equilibrium conditions is the hallmark of the New Empirical Industrial Organization
(NEIO) literature; see Bresnahan (1989) for an overview.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT