Networks of Grievances: Social Capital and Mainstream Party Decline

AuthorFrancesco Colombo,Elias Dinas
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/00104140221100195
Published date01 March 2023
Date01 March 2023
Subject MatterArticles
Article
Comparative Political Studies
2023, Vol. 56(3) 363394
© The Author(s) 2022
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/00104140221100195
journals.sagepub.com/home/cps
Networks of Grievances:
Social Capital and
Mainstream Party
Decline
Francesco Colombo
1
and Elias Dinas
2
Abstract
Why does support for mainstream parties decline? A growing literature
points to economic loss as a source of political resentment. We bring this
explanation one step further. We posit that the local economy qualif‌ies the
role of social capital in forging systemic support. When the economy thrives,
social capital buffers discontent via interpersonal interactions. When the
economy declines it exacerbates discontent, leading to a diffusion of griev-
ances. We test our networks of grievanceshypothesis in two settings. We
f‌irst test our theory in Italy, which offers individual-level information together
with f‌ine-grained municipality-level social capital data. Second, we test the
mechanism underlying our theory combining survey and local administrative
data across 18 European countries. The results suggest that networks of
grievancesoperate as channels of political discussions with peers, converting
retrospective evaluations into systemic discontent bringing non-mainstream
parties into voterschoice sets.
Keywords
local economy, anti-establishment, social interactions, weak ties
1
Aarhus University, Denmark
2
European University Institute, Italy
Corresponding Author:
Francesco Colombo, Department of Political Science, Aarhus University, Bartholins Alle 7, 8000,
Aarhus C, Denmark.
Email: fc@ps.au.dk
Donald Trumps election, followed by the Brexit referendum, invited col-
ourful accounts about the rising appeal of anti-systemic political actors. An
ever-growing literature documents the decline of mainstream party support
(Benedetto et al., 2020;De Vries & Hobolt, 2020;Hobolt & Tilley, 2016) and
sheds light on its implications for policy output (Folke, 2014), mainstream
partiesissue stances (Abou-Chadi, 2016), and democratic norms in more
general (Valentim, 2021). More often than not, however, the major scope of
this literature is to unpack the factors lying behind the decline of mainstream
party support.
1
A stubborn empirical pattern that emerges from this work is
that support for non-mainstream parties is not uniformly distributed
(Colantone & Stanig, 2018b;Golder, 2016), but rather geographically
concentratedeither in rural areas (F¨
ortner et al., 2021), or in urban areas with
looming economic prospects (Broz et al., 2021). The question that naturally
arises has to do with the determinants of this relationship. What makes some
areas more responsive to anti-establishment discourse than others?
The canonical response in the literature is twofold. On the one hand, the
place of residence stands as the aggregation of specif‌ic individual-level
characteristics (Maxwell, 2019). People that share sociodemographic out-
looks and attitudinal prof‌iles cluster together (Sussell, 2013). The role of
context in this case is to sort individuals with taste for non-mainstream parties
together. What then accounts for such preferences typically operates at the
individual-level. On the other hand, context can be the direct cause of such
preferences. Areas hit by economic (Ansell et al., 2021;Adler & Ansell, 2020;
Bisgaard et al., 2016;Colantone & Stanig, 2018c) or other (Hopkins, 2010)
types of shocks may see their residents grow dissatisf‌ied with mainstream
parties, either because they experience directly the consequences of the shock
(Anelli et al., 2021;Colantone & Stanig, 2018c), or because they have de-
veloped an attachment to the community and thus act by responding to losses
in group status (Bolet, 2021). This idea is particularly prominent in recent
ethnographic work (see Cramer, 2016), which speaks of a moral community:
people interact with one another and form loyalties to one another and to the
places in which their interaction takes place(Wuthnow, 2019).
This study enters the fray by proposing an additional mechanism through
which local communities can become hubs of non-mainstream support.
Building on Granovetter (1985), our departure point is that individuals are
neither tied to nor independent of their social environment. Individual re-
actions to the same exogenous stimulus can differ, while at the same time
communities are not the mere sum of their individual parts. Their interde-
pendence and connectedness will shape the resulting behaviour of a com-
munity (Coleman, 1994;Huckfeldt & Sprague, 1987;Katz & Lazarsfeld,
2017). Interconnectedness, in turn, will depend on the local social capital
endowments, what Putnam also def‌ined as the networks of civic engage-
ment(1993). Between a conceptualization of context as the amalgamation of
364 Comparative Political Studies 56(3)
individual interests, fears and perceptions and one in which context forms
group identitieswhich then guide preferenceswe argue that communities
matter by providing information to their residents, and that the amount of
information will, in turn, depend on the density of interactions between an
individual and her community. People develop weak ties, that is, information-
carrying local interactions with the potential to affect individuals in unex-
pected ways. While not driven by the willingness to discuss about politics,
such interactions often end up opening the way to conversations rich in
political content. In so doing, they help individuals update their priors about
otherspreferences and as a result alter their own preferences either through
persuasion or via a change in perceptions about what is acceptable within their
reference group (Bicchieri, 2016).
Two corollaries stem from this idea. First, local interactions will matter
when they contain new information. This is more likely when communities
have experienced a change in their perceived well-being, either on economic
or non-economic grounds. For example, economic loss leads to grievances,
which travel across the community through cheap talk. This point takes us to
the second corollary: grievances are more likely to spread when communities
are more interconnected. Interconnectedness, in turn, is, almost by def‌inition,
higher in areas vested with social capital. Taken together, these two impli-
cations lead us to our key expectation, namely that, else equal, social capital
will undermine the support for mainstream parties when the local community
is f‌illed with grievances.
There are two key ingredients in our argument, the underlying mood in the
community and the intensity of interactions between its members. The former
serves to denote the overall direction in the effects of weak ties, while the latter
moderates their strength in inf‌luencing individualsbeliefs and preferences.
Although the underlying mood could be shaped by both economic and non-
economic factors, we focus here on the former, as they are more tangible to
measure at the community level. We posit that when the local economy is
doing poorly, individual networks will be dense of malaise. Individuals
experiencing an economic loss will f‌ind conf‌irmation to their discontent in
other peoples experiences and opinions. Doing so will diffuse distrust to-
wards established political institutions, facilitating the attribution of re-
sponsibility on the parties more blatantly representing them, including but not
limited to the incumbent. Social capital enhances the density of interactions
and enriches their content. It makes such encounters both more frequent and
more meaningful, leading dissatisf‌ied individuals to update either their
preferences or their perceptions as to how popular these preferences are, or
both. On the contrary, when the economy is doing well, economic discontent
will be more sporadic, leaving little room for social networks to fuel anti-
systemic support, if not suppressing it.
Colombo and Dinas 365

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT